Tuesday, January 15, 2013

FUSION DELIRIUM? Or…… A FUSION ECONOMY?


FUSION DELIRIUM? Or…… A FUSION ECONOMY?

Ganga Prasad Rao
gprasadrao.blogspot.com

It seemed grotesque, even bizarre….Nuclear technology, far from being the ‘milch cow’ it promised to be, had turned in to white elephants for the scale of upfront investment in technology and infrastructure, the expenditures necessary to ensure safety in operation and obtain ‘public approval’, and for the costs of disposal of nuclear waste that were in fact testimony to the poor foresight of nuclear scientists, policy makers and government financing institutions. Hundreds of billions of dollars, perhaps even a magnitude higher of resources, spent on nuclear research over the decades, whether at home or internationally, under unilateral or multi-lateral, covert or overt programs, had come to roost on national and global macro-finances, and was threatening to be the proverbial last straw on the camel’s back, perhaps even the excuse villains on Wall Street were waiting for to crash the global financial markets. But, the alternative was just as depressing. A fossil fuel mania was warming the earth, choking large masses of humanity with cancerous emissions, and inducing slow, but sure changes that were forcing the burden of higher costs of insuring climate risks upon the masses. Besides, whether for reasons of resource exhaustion – real or imagined - the price of fossil fuel, and with it the basket of indexed fuel and energy substitutes, had risen to cause the subsidy budgets in developing nations to balloon and spill over to the international debt and currency markets. And then, there were other deep and grave issues to worry about. Protagonists of a Closed cycle material economy and environmentalists fearing the irreversible loss of air, water, and land from resource extraction and consumption were thwarted by resource barons who insisted on exhausting all reserves – fossil fuel and hard rock - they had discovered with advanced technology. Pricey nuclear research had been sponsored and funded by the Sheikhs, and they, despite an obvious conflict of interest, now had a controlling stake in determining the pace and dissemination of nuclear advances and its commercial exploitation. Nuclear technology could be put to dual use and find its way to terrorists and mercenaries who themselves were pawns for ‘entities’ blackmailing the international financial markets. On another front, the nexus between vendors of obsolete and unproven environmentally risky nuclear technology, the ‘democratically elected’ representatives of developing nations, and the Finance-Insurance megaliths put at risk the health, safety and lives of millions of citizens. Elsewhere, ‘peaceful’ nuclear research could turn economically strategic, and militarily dangerous, if it endowed one nation with energy superiority. The prognosis was stark and dark. Humanity, at the edge of a leap to the stars, was falling short, and perhaps headed for the chasm of unsustainability, even anarchy.
……………………..
With a grimacing look at results spit out by the ‘Tera-Hz’ computer, the Fusion Lab Section Head retorted “………..Yes, but why is the power generated in the reaction an exact 6.023 x 10^23 times that predicted in these equations? What explains the surge?” Befuddled, and bubbling with unmitigated ‘enthusiasmo’, the young and brilliant CERN intern, a post-doc impatiently awaiting his day in the Sun, turned to his senior colleague and blurted “Surely, …..Could it be?...But no,….But yes….indeed…Yes….No….YES.” The theory, experiments and observations could only mean one and only one thing….”FUSION”, … that too, at Avogadro scale ! The wizened, and certainly the more pessimistic colleague, now looking forward not as much to a sunny day as to a Golden sunset, was more subdued. He had many supervised many interns, researchers and scientists in his long careers, each one with a claim to fusion glory, only to fall by the wayside upon investigation. Perhaps out of memory and habit, he turned sarcastic and remarked “Say bye bye to King Coal, heh?.” But, regaining his composure in a trice, he quickly summed up the situation. True, they had conducted a dozen runs of the experiment with startling repetition of the ‘molar multiplier effect’. Despite what was a rare, exotic, and admittedly, very costly to produce isotope to trigger it, the reaction, once initiated, was ‘closed’, self-sustaining and generated power at ‘zero cost’. All evidence pointed to fusion as the source of the power surge. He couldn’t but agree it was indeed just that. It was time to go ‘public’, which, in professional lingo, meant going to the scientific press….
………….

These issues and concerns had not been lost on the ‘Judges’ drawn from the Academia, Think-tanks, the Jurisprudence, Governments, Industry Associations, the Global Insurance Houses, and indeed, the International Organizations: the UNEP-WB-IAEA-IEA-IMF, as they grasped the significance of the once-in-a-millennium development, news of which had been circulated among them by, wink wink, one in the ‘Scientific Press’. Brooding privately, brainstorming together, then hinting privately and airing their views in public, they resolved to make a clean break from the errors of past decades that had pushed the world to the brink of disaster. Agreeing to eschew private or national interests, they forged a partnership for the common good of all humanity. They decreed that the historical technological opportunity be exploited to achieve an all-encompassing concept of ‘global sustainability’, a cause large enough to stand the test of trial of stakeholders from all quarters, particularly its fossil fuel detractors.

Aware of the multiple conflicts that would arise along the way, the Judges strategically chose not to entrust their sustainability agenda with any one institution. Instead, they preferred an oversight body constituted from organizations representing the Environment, Insurance, Financing and Commerce to design, administer, and monitor the ‘Sustainability cause’. Prudently, they chose the UNEP, the IIS, the World Bank, and the IISD with the responsibility to administer and execute their sustainability agenda, and christened it the UIWI. To ensure the UIWI would not be subverted from within or blackmailed from without, they imposed a further condition that all exploitation of nuclear technology would be subservient to, and motivated, beyond the reclamation of past nuclear investments, by the sacrosanct and all-encompassing goal of Global Social Sustainability - Sustainability measured in the aggregate, and in the broadest sense, that encompassed public ESH standards and risks, efficiency and productivity, stability of Government finances, social and military peace, living standards that subsumed public subsidies, and indeed, equity goals, in particular, wages, employment, and cross-sectional as well as inter-generational social justice. The judges required this aggregate and all-encompassing measure of Global Social Sustainability, S, be measured quantitatively, even with a nested, multi-tiered index. Fearing the Governments of the world and Fossil fuel interests would collude at the auctions to delay and deny humanity a sustainable future, the Judges sought to further ensure that the Sustainability target, S*, was reached at the earliest future time point, T*. They also entrusted the commercialization of Fusion technology to the IAEA (in the opposite of the IEA which operated the Carbon permit market) and decreed that nuclear technology compete on both costs and externalities with existing technologies, and further that the best way to ensure the commercialization would be to auction Fusion Licenses, FL, exclusively to Governments around the world.

To this end, and by a special arrangement with the IMF (which was ordained upon to serve as a repository of all ‘nuclear-debt’ from all nations), and the fiduciary organizations of member nations, the Judges provided for the institution of a ‘Sustainability Pot’ - verily a large reserve of Gold deposited against the SDR credits extended to the nations of the world. The Judges permitted this SDR Gold, meant to be held in reserve and therefore illiquid, to be contingently leveraged and issued as liquid Gold ETFs to the financial markets. In special cases, the IMF even permitted the ‘proxy accounting’ of other illiquid gold stocks such as jewellery gold, non-ETF gold, and (capitalized) gold reserves held either among households and banks, or ‘in ground’ by the State. Such interpretation was advantageous for it permitted the IMF to endogenously compute an aggregate average ‘SDR Gold to Gold ETF Multiplier’ as that value which when applied to the aggregate SDR Gold reserves, solved for and equalled the nuclear debt burden. This ‘monetization’ of illiquid SDR Gold in to liquid Gold ETFs enabled the IMF to kick-start the process and persuade stakeholders to seek a faster path to sustainability.

Rather than directly favour the UIWI with as large a pot as they had created, they entrusted the IMF to raise resources by issuing tranches of Sustainability Bonds against the Gold ETFs created from the ‘monetization’ of SDR Gold - sponsored by various nation-stakeholders that was not unlike replacing ‘inherited family gold’ with gold demat units. Instead, the Judges granted the UIWI something much more tangible, the property rights to entire world’s natural assets in the Commons. They authorised the UIWI to offer NAETFs – ETFs of Natural Assets - essentially the post-capitalization parcelling of these publicly held Common assets, the Oceans and Inland Nature Heritage reserves as tranches of ‘Nature shares’ on the international equity markets, and budget its activities with the proceeds.

The UIWI initiated the process by partnering the nations of the world as they sought to ‘monetize’ the illiquid SDR Gold holdings as liquid Gold ETFs – a prerequisite for the issue of Sustainability bonds by the IMF, and in itself an intricate, multi-step process that involved the highest bidding nation (the one that offered the highest SDR Gold to Gold ETF long-run return multiplier) to sponsor the ‘ripping’ of SDR Gold to Gold ETFs. The sponsoring nation (or, conceivably, other entities such as, despite the conflicts of interest, the World Bank, ‘Sheikhs’, or even the Industry) offered a ‘Blue Diamond I’, equal ‘Green 2key Green I Green Bakey’ to UIWI to initiate the ‘ripping’. It first exchanged its SDR Gold for the indivisible ‘(Green) 2 Money Bakey’ that the UIWI offered from Recycling markets. In turn, the UIWI ‘ripped’ the SDR Gold in to a new tranche of Gold ETF units at the SDR Gold multiplier rate, plus a ‘(Blue Diamond) I Dollar’ and net of a ‘Judge Stepdown Green I Green Bakey’ (approx equal ‘(Green) 2 Money Bakey’, and hence a ‘WB Ripping 100%’), in the process causing the price of Gold to fall. The sponsoring nation partnered the IMF in the ‘High frequency Stepdown-Exchange Trading’ (HFT) of Gold ETF for SDR Gold. (The UIWI also boasted the power to ‘un-rip’ the Gold ETFs back in to SDR Gold on a need basis if the constituent keys were offered simultaneously. A Volatility ZS 2key from the Commodity markets supported volatility in Gold markets during the ripping-unripping process).

Post ripping, the sponsoring Nation could apply the newly created Gold ETFs either toward its global sustainability obligations or its national interests. In the former case, it sponsored the retirement of a tranche of IMF’s nuclear debt by choosing to exchange its Gold ETFs in part for IMF-issued Sustainability Bonds. The IMF, upon receipt of Gold ETFs plus the ‘Dollar I’ key from the sponsoring nation, retired an equal amount of Nuclear debt (for ‘Green Bakey U’) and, simultaneously, issued Sustainability bonds in the same amount. The Sustainability bonds, issued with an ‘I Dollar’ key to the sponsoring nation, were guaranteed by the UIWI. Unlike conventional bonds, these Sustainability bonds were issued, at any point in time, with maturities linked to the attainment of multiple, interim ‘Sustainability targets’, Sk. Thus, these bonds were issued with ‘Short Oo’, ‘Oo Oo’, and ‘Long Oo’ keys as appropriate to their sustainability target and the implied, but uncertain maturity horizon. These targets were re-adjusted upwards with each tranche, and implied variable and endogenous bond durations at various stages of the temporal path to S*. Subsequently, the sponsor Government leveraged the Sustainability Bonds with the ‘I Dollar key’ in its domestic Closed Cycle/IPO/equity market to seek an ‘Equity Oo key Long 2 Share Capital Appreciation’. Investors in Sustainability bonds were returned ‘Green I 2 Money’ upon the maturing of the bonds. In this manner, the monetization of SDR Gold motivated and supported many operations in the grand Sustainability stratagem. If, on the other hand, the sponsoring nation chose to heed its domestic priorities over global sustainability concerns, as for example in times of recessions, then it directed the Gold ETFs (net of S. Bond purchases) either to bid for Fusion licenses, support the Closed cycle industry, sponsor Reserve buybacks, or purchase Carbon permits for its ESHSSEI sector. In making this investment choice, it employed a three-fold criterion – a GDP multiplier, if a short-run decision, equity prices, if intermediate, and a threshold/benchmark expected appreciation in gold prices, if a long investment.

Toward complying with the Judge’s wishes, the UIWI first required the World Bank and the Sheikh-OPEC to take positions in the matter. While the World Bank sought a highly efficient economy with a high PGDP in which Capital and Technology IPR were rewarded, in fact an economy characterised by an early transition to fusion power and a faster, energy-driven progress toward Sustainability, S*, the Sheikh-OPEC preferred a laissez faire approach that perpetuated the era of fossil fuels, and which permitted a slower progress to S* if with a large dose of bond-driven, subsidy-supported social equity. To skirt the conflict of interest inherent in powerful entities such as themselves, the two hedged their positions in the opposite. The Sheikh-OPEC, with the power to set fuel prices, positioned themselves for a PGDP 2key in booms and a Resource Bakey on underexploited fossil fuels in recessions, while the World Bank, with the power to set economic policy, staked the Carbon Permit 2key in booms and a PGDP Bakey in bust. Faced with irreconcilable differences between themselves, and having hedged appropriately, they chose strategically, to permit the UIWI to choose a path of compromise.

Breathing a sigh of relief, and yet fearing the consequences of potentially collusive polar positions of the two heavyweights, the UIWI too hedged itself. It first roped in the Recycling Industry which advocated a middle-of-the-road Closed Cycle Economy. It also invited, on one hand, the global Insurance Houses, and on the other, the energy and mineral resource owners/barons in to its ‘Ring of Sustainability’. It offered to the Insurance Houses a line to subsidize and, by implication, tighten the standards as they applied to risks to public ESH and the Commons in a subsidy-ridden, fossil-fuel dominated world. To the energy/mineral resource owners and barons, the UIWI offered a buyback of ‘economic reserves’ that would potentially be left unexploited in a nuclear/closed cycle future. With these alternatives in place, the UIWI dynamically optimized the path to achieve S* given its initial state, St, and the direct or shadow prices of the various determinants (the endogenous variables of the optimization) of the Sustainability Index, S* subject to various constraints, in particular monetary resources, the state of existing production technology, stability of financial systems, and equity agenda. The optimization, given an arbitrary discount rate, yielded an optimal, cost-minimizing, inter-temporal path for the state variable, St:T* to reach S*. It obtained, beyond the one-period, short-term ‘compromise target’, St+1 acceptable to the two opposing parties, the optimal, cost-minimizing investments in creation of NAETF units, Fusion licenses, ESH subsidies, Recycling, Carbon Permits, as well Reserve buybacks.
……………………..
It was just as well CERN had built the facility underground with elaborate safety precautions. For, the production of Y++248, the isotope, with ‘reversible fissionability’ characteristics so essential to initialize and sustain the closed cycle fusion reaction, required the highest power that the lasers could be operated at. The impact of the electron beams generated so many species that it was difficult to isolate this particular heavier species while retaining its ionic stability. But the brilliant intern found a way. He isolated it by grouping it with other more unstable species, thus ensuring it’d be the last to degenerate in a de-stabilizing environment – an environment that could be perpetuated with the power generated in the fusion reaction! Little did he know he was at the threshold of a Nobel....much less suspect the ‘Senor’ was aware he had opened the door for commercial fusion power generators!
……………………….

Appreciating the UIWI’s hedged and unbiased stance, and privately relieved that the optimization was of a form that permitted flexibility, even substitution across alternative paths to Sustainability, the two combatants affirmed their concurrence with the definition, construction and measurement of the Sustainability Index as directed in the Judges’ decree. And though they differed fundamentally with regard to the target date, T*, for achieving the Sustainability target, S*, they chose strategically and for the immediate year ahead, the ‘compromise target’, St+1, that minimized costs while retaining the option to alter course in the future. As it turned out, that was appropriate from the perspective of the larger welfare of humanity and opportune to the powerful Fossil fuel interests too, who, otherwise, were in position to deny the fusion breakthrough. It provided the basis for intelligent decision-making based upon strategic positioning of the differently resource-endowed nations (and entities) given the spectrum of their priorities, resource endowments and production specializations.




The UIWI, aware of the Sustainability pot entrusted with the IMF by the Judges, wielded its newly vested property rights to the Commons of the world to raise monetary resources necessary to fund their programs toward securing the Sustainability objective. It first delineated all Commons and International Nature Heritage sites, whether on land, sea or ice, straddling different continents and nations, and valued them for replacement cost, opportunity cost, use values and non-use values, to obtain a base of capitalized Common Natural Assets. It then apportioned very small portions of the asset base to create tranches of Natural Asset ETFs, NAETFs. The choice of the ETF route was appropriate not only for the liquidity it endowed the priceless assets with, but also because it permitted the ‘devolution’ of an asset with an extra-ordinarily large capitalized base in multiple, measured tranches of NAETFs linked to the achievement of interim Sustainability targets, Sk. These NAETFs competed against conventional Equities, Bonds, and Fuel/Commodity ETFs as an alternative asset class that offered diversification benefits to investors. The UIWI sought a ‘Blue Diamond I Green Bakey U 2 Bakey I Money’ key for the devolution of the NAETF IPO/FPOs to the capital market (and the same was obtained, respectively, from the sponsor Government, the IMF, the Investors at large, and from Insurers on behalf the Industry). While the various Governments funded their purchase of NAETFs with ‘Sustainability Bond 2 key I Bakey Long Oo’, the Industry directed a ‘Hedge Oo Group insurance’ to buy in to them. The ‘Hedge Oo Group Insurance’ was a strategic investment and the means to derive information on risks as they pertained to their exploitation of the Commons and ensure its ‘sustainable exploitation’. Subsequent to the IPO and support by the Government and the Industry, the NAETFs found favour among the investors at large. Such investors valued the NAETFs, beyond their potential for capital appreciation and asset diversification value, as an instrument to express their active and passive values for the preservation of humanity’s common environmental heritage. From a macro-financial perspective, the NAETFs represented an asset class so large and imperturbable in the short-run, that it was stable against volatilities of multifarious origins, and inured to recessions or macro-shocks that shorted boom economies.
The UIWI re-invested the proceeds of the NAETF FPOs to further its Sustainability agenda. It ‘super-allocated’ the NAETF proceeds 4 ways - between Fossil fuel- and Ore Reserve buybacks, the Closed-cycle agenda and Public ESH risk reduction employing the equalization of marginal impact strategy. The strategy implied that resources were directed to the buyback auctions until their marginal impact on the Sustainability index fell and equalled the rising marginal impact on the Sustainability Index of ploughing it in to Recycling and Public ESH causes. Plainspeak, the UIWI so re-allocated NAETF proceeds that an additional dollar obtained equal sustainability progress across all these four alternatives.
………………………..
If the atmosphere at the Fusion Lab was exciting, and the query session at the Annual Conference of Nuclear Physicists tense and torrid, it was simply electric at the ‘Nobel Hall’. The Nobel committee had broken all traditions to invite a select community of scientists to witness the award. As they received the Nobel jointly, they realized they were living the moment every Scientist dreamt of. The unlikely pair chose to read their Nobel address together, at times agreeing and graciously giving way to the other, sometimes snatching the podium from the other, and through it all recreating how they jabbed and prodded each other in their lab 200 m below surface to come up with ‘the Nobel Spark’, in fact an all-important ‘what if’ question that the less imaginative would have brushed aside….. The ovations seemed to drown away in the effulgence of the spotlights….
………..……………

The IAEA bigwigs considered various mechanisms to allocate Fusion Licences. For obvious reasons of nuclear security, the IAEA would only permit National entities to participate in the allocation of fusion licenses and operate the facility. Those participating Government entities had multiple constituencies, roles and stakes – as past sponsors of nuclear research, as part-commercial-, part-public providers of subsidized power to the masses, and even as proxies for the Industry who sought a lower-cost alternative to conventional, fossil-fuelled power generation. Anticipating the Industry would seek Fusion power through the Government, and not forgetting the IMF had ordained them to recover past investments in nuclear research, the IAEA settled on auctioning licences for Fusion power units so they could extract upfront the rents of commercializing fusion power. As it turned out, that was even appropriate, for the existing fossil fuel industry would not give in to fusion technology until their multi-decade investments were recovered. In fact, it was just as well that the UIWI optimised dynamically across alternatives paths to sustainability for that ensured the IAEA did not put ‘too much’ fusion capacity on the auction table, lest the bids at the Fusion auctions drop dramatically and induce a Sheikh reprisal in the form of an oil glut. That the IEA, nominally it’s ‘sister organization’ simultaneously auctioned non-bankable, transferable, year-specific, annual Carbon Permits several years in to the future, albeit with a ‘buyback option’ was revealing. In the context of a Zero Emission alternative that Fusion technology represented, the auctions helped in better price discovery and enhanced the inter-temporal efficiency of energy markets. The two auctions forced the Government (and the Industry) to make conscious decisions between, on one hand, fossil-fuelled power, fossil energy inputs and carbon permits, and fusion power on the other.

At the auctions, the IAEA offered licences in capacity ranging from 10 MW and 100MW to 1GW of fusion power. The licences permitted the winning bidder to apply the IAEA Fusion technology to generate power continuously and perpetually. At the auctions, representatives of various Governments put in their bids (with a Green 2key) for Fusion capacity consistent with their domestic energy demand, fossil fuel reserves, and such factors as the price of power, the capital cost of conventional power capacity, prevailing discount rates and indeed, the price (vector) of carbon permits, PCP. The IAEA limited the sale of fusion capacity to that indicated by the UIWI from its inter-temporal optimization. The FL Permits won at the auctions were non-transferable, but bankable across time, offering Governments the means to smoothen the process of capacity addition in the power sector consistent with economic opportunities and sectoral constraints. Further, the banking of fusion licences, in arbitrage with fossil-fuelled power capacity, facilitated harmonious integration of energy policy in to short and long politico-economic cycles that nations underwent at various times and for various periods.

The proceeds of the IAEA-supervised FL auctions were placed in a ‘Nuclear Research Recovery Account’, NRRA, operated by the World Bank. The World Bank routed the proceeds two ways depending on a simple criterion: When UIWI in its next-round ‘sustainability compromise’ favoured the efficiency of Fusion technology, and the licences so auctioned improved the outlook for global sustainability, the World Bank invested the Gold ETFs (with Green 2key) that constituted its proceeds from fusion auctions toward financing additional tranches of Sustainability bonds and NAETFs. In such times, it was also opportune for the beneficiaries of the Reserve buyback auctions to apply their funds to sponsor the conversion of SDR Gold to Gold ETFs at a high multiple. At other times when the UIWI favoured equity over efficiency, and the subsidy economy expanded unsustainably to stimulate the Carbon permit market and boost the prices of Sustainability Bonds, the World Bank chose instead to re-convert its Gold ETFs back to SDR Gold at a low multiple. With this strategy, the World Bank insured itself from the travails of the ‘equity regime’ and positioned itself for the rise in the SDR Gold multiplier that preceded the switch back to an ‘efficiency regime’. In such increasingly unsustainable times, it also directed a bakey (or a Share) from the Green 2key from FL auctions to the NAETF markets where it exploited its volatility against the FF-ETFs and Non-FF Commodity ETFs (the volatility originating from the inefficient exploitation of the commons).

The Carbon Permit Auctions, administered by the IEA, operated in the opposite of the FL auction market. Having generated an inter-temporal Sustainability path and noting its implications for the path of carbon permits given current prices and CO2 concentration, the IEA, on behalf UIWI, offered transferable, non-bankable but year-specific, annual Carbon Permits for up to several years in future at the auctions. It did however provide for a ‘buyback’ of the permits enabling auction participants to bid confidently in the context of concurrent fusion power auctions. Bristling at being required to follow the directions of the UIWI as regards the number of permits to put up for the auction, the Sheikh-OPEC sought bids from various Industry verticals /aggregate Commercial entities for the Carbon permits on offer. Unlike at the IAEA FL auctions, where only the Government agencies could participate, the IEA permitted cross-national economic and environmental aggregates to participate in the permit auctions. For political and economic reasons, carbon consuming entities aggregated as follows:

1.       ESH, Subsidy and Social Equity Interests, ESHSSEI, typically represented by the Government and comprising of:
a.       Agriculture
b.      The Traditional Poor
c.       Public ESH services
d.      Sectors generating positive externalities, including Public Infrastructure
2.       Renewable Energy Interests, REI, and International Environmental Organizations, IEO.
3.       Fossil Fuel Interests, FFI:
a.       Coal
b.      Oil
c.       Gas
d.      FF Utilities
4.       Hard Rock Mining, HRM
5.       Manufacturing, MFTR
6.       Transport, TRN, and
7.       IT & Service Industries, ITSI

These aggregates of various production and service sectors as well as equity interests, each required to inventory and pay upfront for their carbon emissions, aggregated demand for carbon permits from their constituent firms/members down their vertical, then faced off against each other in the IEA auctions and secured carbon permits for the current, and conceivably, future years as well. In essence, the Industry and the Commercial entities paid for their energy (and open-cycle) inefficiency (an Inefficiency 2key) with the purchase of Carbon permits. Bids reflected the participants’ assessment of economic activity, prices of energy alternatives, and indeed, sectoral prospects for the immediate year and the years ahead. The FFIs and the REI-IEOs competed for Carbon permits albeit for diametrically opposite reasons: the former bundled them with fuel/power sales as they deemed appropriate; the latter either participated in the auctions with a net carbon deficit and therefore offered carbon credits to the IEA consistent with prevailing permit prices, and/or bought away and invalidated low-priced emission permits to shrink the annual carbon inventory. The ESHSSEI, funded largely by the Government (and Foreign Aid?), purchased carbon permits for goods and services subsidized to the socially vulnerable, to support activities considered vital to the economy, and for the remediation of past ESH follies. The competition for permits across the various aggregate entities revealed the societal trade-offs between, on one hand, equity and efficiency, in particular the values for subsidy programs for essential goods and services against public infrastructure, and on the other, between various industry sectors and verticals. In export sectors like Manufacturing, and sectors with trans-national aggregation, such as Transport, the second-tier auction involved bidding at the national level which in turn determined production allocations across nations. The 2-tier carbon permit auctions constituted an expedient, second-best means to efficiently allocate global production and trade. Bids for carbon prices internalized the presence and operation of an FL market as well as UIWI’s programs involving the Materials recycling market.

At both the FL and the CP auctions, the UIWI retained the option to intervene in subsequent rounds and overtly match auction bids to varying extents that were funded with a ‘(Carbon/SDR) Bear bakey (Commodity) Yo Yo ZS (Nuclear) Growth Oo key’. This policy created ‘Subsidy FLs’ and ‘Subsidy CPs’ and ensured the Sustainability Index achieved St+1, its one period, short-term goal. Revenues from the auction of Carbon Permits accrued with the ‘Subsidy Fund-Foreign Aid’ account under the aegis of the Sheikh-OPEC. Preferring a ‘checks and balances’ strategy, they leveraged the funds from the account either to arbitrage and stabilize FF ETFs against Commodity market-induced volatility, or tilt the economies of consuming nations toward oil by subsidizing the more energy/carbon-intensive among them (who were, possibly, also recipients of the UIWI-subsidized carbon permits), thus ensuring permit revenues were reinvested to obtain either an immediate return or a long-term return.

Next, the auction participants either apportioned or re-auctioned these permits back to the constituent members of the aggregate. The IEA permitted the within-aggregate re-assignment of Carbon permits across nations, but not its cross-sectoral re-sale or inter-temporal banking. (As it turned out, this was consistent not only with international trade that had turned political boundaries meaningless, but also put a spoke in the designs of politicians and ‘macro-economists’ who conspired to trigger and time macro -cycles that turned speculation in carbon permits a means to cover industry losses; On the contrary, enabling the cross-border, within-aggregate ‘re-auction’ of Carbon permits put paid to currency exchange conspiracies and even served to secure the fortunes of the sectoral aggregate and stabilize international currency trade). This hierarchical re-auctioning technique, presuming unbiased (competitive) estimation of demand, served as a natural filter to favour the environmentally and economically more efficient firms over other firms within the aggregate. As they competed against one another in the second-tier auctions, firms within a vertical revealed the opportunities and the sectoral shadow values of carbon across nations.

In pursuing its Closed-cycle agenda, the UIWI, through the network of Governments, channelled Closed Cycle funds, specifically a ‘Sustainability Bakey Share CC 2key’ from the NAETF pot to the Recycling market even as the Industry and Commercial Sector contributed a ‘Recycling Oo Share’. It was apparent that resource-poor nations with a large consumption base had the largest stake in a Closed cycle economy. These funds were directed either as tonnage/value/tolling subsidies, or as capital investment in firms that engaged in recycling. While product tonnage subsidies favoured recycled materials that generated scale-economies, and value-based tolling subsidies targeted the higher-priced recycled materials, tolling discounts permitted recyclers to offer either lower prices or incrementally higher quality to consumers of recycled metals and materials.

To determine the optimal amount of funds to direct to this cause within the ambit of the super-optimization by the UIWI, national governments chose a simple, if a tentative and subjective criterion. They channelled funds to the recycling industry until its marginal cost of capital fell to, and equalled the prospective appreciation in the price of gold in the long term. As the price of Gold and its expected appreciation fell with enhancements in sustainability, these policies facilitated the expansion of the Recycling sector, in the limit replacing the entire primary metal mining industry when Gold prices flattened out in to the far future. The Recycling market offered a Recycle Bakey to the Commodity market to complement the Commodity 2key offered by the assemblage of Industrial/Commercial users. A Commodity Bakey was directed to the Fossil Fuel ETF market (which arbitraged against the Gold ETFs as they expanded incrementally with conversion from SDR Gold).

Cognizant of the role public environment, health and safety played in enhancing sustainability, and the impact of dispersed anthropogenic activities on the same, the UIWI, which had already included ESH arguments in its Sustainability Index, now chose to actively support it under the aegis of the IIS despite the obvious conflict of interest. The support took the form of loaned ‘working capital’ funds to the ESH Insurance Houses derived from the ripping of SDR Gold to Gold ETFs (the ‘WB Ripping 100%’). The UIWI lent these funds to the Insurance Houses at a rate equal the differential between, on one hand, the returns on NAETFs and non-FF Commodity ETFs, and on the other, between the returns on FF ETFs and Gold ETFs. This construct ensured that the ‘interest rate subsidy’ on working capital loans expanded as the world lurched toward unsustainability, providing the Insurance sector with timely funds and ensuring that society paid a price for its ill-advised profligacy. These low cost funds served to expand business opportunities of Insurance Houses beyond their current risk threshold until their Marginal IRR, MIRR, fell to the cost of working capital. In layman’s terms, the availability of low cost funds enabled the Insurance Houses to offer attractive insurance premia on, and incrementally secure what would otherwise have been, in unsustainable times, costly ESH/Commons risks to insure, thus expanding insurance and enhancing Sustainability.

Prescient as the UIWI was, it anticipated fossil fuel reserves would be laid waste in a world of fusion power, as would mineral reserves in a Closed Cycle economy – both of which were explicit goals under its charge. Given the economic resources invested in exploring for, and developing discovered energy and mineral resources, and the capitalization of resource firms in the equity markets, it was necessary to provide for a defensible means for anticipating those impacts. Anticipating that the shadow value of energy and mineral reserves would fall in a world with fusion power and closed cycle economy, and induce resource owners to seek a means to sell or liquidate them pre-emptively, the UIWI instituted a Reserve buyback scheme. Under the scheme, the UIWI would, in periodic Reverse Auctions, seek offers for liquidation of fossil energy and mineral reserves (with the exception of Gold reserves), and accept the more attractive offers subject to availability of resources. The monetary resources for these buybacks were sourced from NAETF tranches. The UIWI sought the assistance of the UNDP to conduct the reserve buyback auctions on its behalf and bankrolled it with proceeds from tranches of NAETF FPOs as implied by its ‘super-allocation’ algorithm across alternative causes. The super-allocation of resources implied the fulfillment of a marginal criterion in the reserve buyback auctions as well. In general terms, reserve buybacks were pursued with NAETF FPO proceeds until the rising marginal shadow price of energy/mineral reserve due the reserves buyback just equalled the marginal finding cost of incremental reserves. Incremental reserve buybacks were indicated until prospective returns across Gold, NAETFs and expected appreciation in the marginal shadow price of energy and mineral reserves equilibrated and equalled the long-run cost of capital. At this point, there was no further incentive to either invest or divest incrementally, thus defining the achievement of the optimum reserve buyback.

To tide over the issue of excessive competition for reserve buybacks and to identify potential uses post-liquidation, the UNDP required that the reserves be ‘sponsored’ by one of several entities, each representing a different constituency/use. Thus, an offshore oil field reserve required the sponsorship of the WWF, the IMO, or other organisations with similar interest. Inland fossil energy and mineral reserves, whether under exploitation or otherwise, required the sponsorship of an agricultural body like the FAO, a tourism body akin the UNWTO, or an Apex Industry association which intended to develop the property for industrial/commercial use post the auctions. This policy brought about the sale of marginal fossil fuel and mineral ‘assets’, that were at risk of turning infra-marginal, to sponsors who themselves faced a ‘threshold return’ with their post-buyout plans in the prospective return on Gold ETFs or Sustainability Bonds. That many such reserves were owned by the Government and either leased to private entities or publicly-owned firms was an issue, even a concern. For various financial, accounting, resource-economics reasons, it was necessary to limit the buyback auctions to firms capitalised and listed on global stock exchanges. Since these resources were tied to long-term leases, it was often also necessary for joint assent, even a negotiated deal between the Government, the leaseholder, and the sponsor prior to the auctions.

Aware there could be a paucity of sponsors and that the same sponsor might be interested in multiple reserve parcels, the UNDP conducted auctions by seeking 3-part ‘separately sealed’ liquidation offers for both virgin and ‘in-use’ fossil energy and mineral reserves. Offers for reserve liquidation consisted of a) submissions on ‘ore price-ore reserve tonnage’ schedule, along with a portfolio of data on various field/ore body characteristics, b) the confidential offer to liquidate reserves and turn over property to the sponsor, and c) the sponsor’s confidential Bid (drawn on its pre-registered ‘line’ with the UNDP)-cum-Rezoning plans for the property. These offers were as cognizant of UIWI’s ‘equalization of marginal impact on Sustainability index’ criterion for the allocation of auction funds as they were of those alternative causes competing for the proceeds of the NAETF FPO pot. While the Offer to liquidate reserves captured the PV of the expected future stream of profits (net of reclamation costs), the confidential Bid reflected the sponsor’s rents that would accrue from the proposed re-zoning plans for the property. Denoting the reserve liquidation offers as ‘payouts’ and the sponsor bids as ‘receipts’, the UNDP computed ‘Net payouts’ associated with each liquidation offer and sorted them in order of increasing payouts. The agency then serially bought back reserves ‘en-block’ until funds for reserves buyback, as allotted by the UIWI, were exhausted. This turned out to be a better strategy than to merely buy back reserves in order of increasing offers because it guaranteed an early return of the reserve parcels to an alternative, beneficial use. However, it did not provide for the possibility that a large re-zoning bid, uncorrelated with ‘Ore reserve tonnage – Liquidation offer’ schedule, would upset the expected order of reserve buybacks, and induce cascading impacts on Commodity and FF ETF markets. The ‘auction winners’ were compensated for the loss of their production reserves with ‘Green Bakey Sponsor Oo’ money. Whereas offshore reserves bought away added to the base of natural assets upon which the NAETFs were created, inland reserve parcels, whether mined or otherwise, were put to use as stated by the sponsoring agency in its re-zoning bid. Over time, and as the price of fossil fuels and minerals fell due the expansion of fusion power and closed cycle economy, these auctions incrementally reduced the un-economic portion of reserves until only those (fuels, ores,) mines and refiners survived who could stand up to the efficiencies of fusion power economics and Closed cycle recycling. Exploration for new resources, however, continued until such time as when the marginal finding cost of reserves increased, and simultaneously approached, both, the (falling) shadow marginal prices of the fossil fuel/energy reserve acquisition in the equity markets, and the rising marginal offer on reserve liquidation in the reserve auctions. Further, only the lowest cost, and highly-informative geophysical techniques survived in the market for energy/mineral exploration.

The proceeds of mineral and fossil fuel reserve buybacks could be re-invested either in SDR Gold, Sustainability bonds, or in Commodity-ETF markets depending on the identity of the owner/lease-holder, and the UIWI ‘regime’. Thus, the proceeds from FFRA buyback (with a ‘Green Bakey’ key) and Ore Reserve Auction Fund, ORAF, (with ‘I Money Bakey’) could, in sustainable regimes, be combined with the ‘Green 2key I Bakey’ from Fusion Licence auctions (‘I Bakey I Money Bakey’ serving as an approximation of ‘Green I’) and leveraged to invest in and un-rip SDR Gold to Gold ETF along with a ‘Dollar I key’ or an ‘I Dollar key, or, in less sustainable times, either invested in Sustainability Bonds, or combined with the ‘Growth Bakey’ from carbon permit auction funds, CPAF, to obtain a ‘100% return key’ upon investment in the Commodity-FF ETF markets. The IMF, sponsoring governments, Fossil fuel exploration and Commodity trading firms sought the ‘Dollar I’/’I Dollar’ for their investments in bond and equity markets.
………………………
There they stood, rather non-descript but for the ‘Danger-Keep away’ sign on them, in sizes from an Oil barrel to a Petroleum storage tank. There were no appendages, not much piping, and certainly no chimneys. If there was anything prominent or noticeable about them, it was the cables – cables thicker than your arms. These ‘Power up or Pee’ units, christened ‘PuoP units’, had been designed to be modular and scalable. The units required initialization, a procedure that involved plugging in the ‘super-secret’ isotope canister, always maintained at 5K to ensure radioactive-(in)stability, inside the reactor. So designed, that once initialized, they’d either operate normally and generate power continuously without as much a hum, or literally and merely, ‘pee’ water and stop, their biggest secret was also their biggest selling point - Power output. The PuoP units scaled at an exponent, so that while an entire town could be served its power demand with a single-canister, barrel-sized unit, a city with all its residents and commercial establishments, not to mention plug-in EV outlets, would only need a multi-canister unit the size of a small OHT. As for those Petroleum storage tank-sized units, one would have to site them either at the international border with twin-cities on either side sharing a common power grid, by EAF mega-clusters, or massive desalination plants serving an entire water-starved desert nation.
……………….

Gold, the ‘eternal’ store of value, and verily the benchmark for the standard that bore its name in many a matter, was a ‘refuge’ from everything that was unsustainable, and which needed to be postponed to the future (as opposed to being corrected thru issue of bonds). Gold ETFs served many purposes in the grand stratagem. They served as Collateral for the IMF’s issue of Sustainability Bonds. The price of Gold ETF served, both in absolute terms and in terms of expected return, as a benchmark for various prices and marginal shadow values in the grand sustainability stratagem. Gold ETFs faced new competition in NAETFs and equilibrated to a new, lower price level consistent with the emergence of an alternative asset class. Gold prices fell and those of NAETFs rose until the two equilibrated, implicitly defining a Gold benchmark/price for Natural assets. Given the broad, comprehensive nature of the Sustainability Index, its strong negative correlation with Gold was trivially anticipated. However, the same had large repercussions on the various stakeholders and operations in the grand UIWI Sustainability stratagem. As expected appreciation in Gold prices declined with sustainability enhancements over time, so did the benchmarks for investments in recycling and apportionment of reserve buyback funds. Thereafter, Gold ETF prices fell, ceteris paribus, with incremental conversion of SDR Gold to Gold ETFs, and appreciated post the dilution of the capitalized Natural Asset in subsequent NAETF FPOs until prospective return on Gold equalled an endogenously sustainable rate - in the limit, the cost of capital in a Closed cycle economy. The inordinately large impact NAETFs had on Gold prices implied that the number and size of subsequent tranches of NAETFs influenced the SDR Gold ripping multiplier as well, in turn determining resource allocation decisions within the Sustainability strategy.

At the end of the first round, the UIWI verified and accounted the various transactions and the extent to which they dovetailed with the optimality rules as required by its dynamic optimization. Come the next round, the combatants took the same position. Again, and due the re-surfacing of disagreement between the World Bank and the Sheikhs, the UIWI generated a dynamic, ‘compromise’ path between their extreme positions. It took account of deviations from the previous round, including banked FLs, Carbon Permit auction prices, reserve buybacks (including subsidized rounds), the various costs of capital, sectoral MIRRs and imputed shadow values, as well as the current value of the Sustainability Index in re-computing the optimal path, St+1:T* to achieve the S* utopia. The re-computed dynamic path for S* implied a new interim target, St+2, for the immediate period ahead. Such periodic iterations recurred across years and decades until the St+k converged toward S*.

At its annual meeting, the UIWI reviewed the interim outcomes – both intended, and the surprises. The creation of NAETFs caused an overnight increment to the set of alternative asset classes. It provided household investors, beyond a liquid alternative to Equities, Bonds, Gold/FF & Commodity ETFs, a credible means to express their support for the preservation of the environment. Those belonging to Industry and Commerce, who did not participate in the Group Insurance that covered them for the risk of natural and anthropogenic disasters in the Commons, bought in to NAETFs with a ‘Green bakey’. The goal-linked issue of subsequent tranches of NAETFs brought about tangible improvements in arguments constituting the Sustainability Index, in particular public ESH indicators. The buybacks of energy and mineral resources with the proceeds of NAETFs permitted an orderly transition to a world characterised by fusion power and closed cycle. Over time, growth in income due broad-based productivity gains brought about by Fusion power enhanced sustainable lifestyle and stimulated incremental demand for energy. As Fusion power took hold, carbon prices dipped and induced a rebound in the demand for fossil fuels that were already being propped up with overt subsidies.

Elsewhere, the support offered to Insurance Houses with low cost, loaned working capital funds brought about a world in which a much larger set of private and public risks, as well as risks to the Commons were insured. A more comprehensive coverage of risks meant that the society was better prepared to handle natural and anthropogenic risks and disasters, compensate damages, and if the latter, correct the cause, and thus bring about a significantly more sustainable environs, society and economy.

It was just as appropriate, even expedient that various entities, from the Government, the Industry, and International organizations sought to sponsor the conversion of existing energy and mineral reserve holdings from their primary use to an alternative, different use. The subsidization of reserve auctions with NAETF proceeds helped bring about a faster ‘retirement’ of existing and planned mines. The mechanism of sponsorship at the Reserve buyback auctions, beyond ensuring an alternative use and hastening it, facilitated the re-circulation of auction proceeds to reconvert Gold ETFs to SDR Gold and thus re-start the Sustainability Bond –Nuclear Debt Retirement – NAETF FPO ‘circle of virtue’. The reserve buyback proceeds potentially also supported the recycling industry and the subsidization of fusion power auction rounds. The buyback auctions, which provided a cushion against irreversibilities involving disequilibrium in reserve holdings, tempered volatility in Commodity markets that tracked the risk and uncertainty of business in Mining. The fall in prospective gold returns and the subsidization of capital to the recycling industry consistent with a lower cost of capital benchmark, implied an enlargement of the Closed cycle economy both absolutely and relative to the primary metals industry. The primary metals industry, faced with a larger risk premium to the otherwise declining cost of capital, shrank to a niche limited either to high product quality and/or metals and materials whose quality deteriorated with recycling. In the long-run, when energy and the mineral reserve buyback markets achieved equilibrium and new reserve discoveries merely kept pace with reserve liquidation, when exploration turned in to merely a search for lower cost reserves, and when the entire capitalized base of natural assets had been ‘devolved’ as NAETFs, the world approached the Sustainability optimum, S*.

Finally, the Judges examined the drivers of the system to satisfice themselves the system would self-perpetuate until utopia. They were notably, economic and financial. The financial incentives to participate in the system involved the potential for gains in SDR monetization, the recovery of nuclear debt and consequent impact upon the financial markets, the potential for asset diversification and capital appreciation accompanying the rolling out of the NAETFs, the availability of near-zero cost working capital, as well as funds for the buyback of energy and ore reserves. The Volatility ZS 2key exploited by the Sheikhs-OPEC (in the Commodity-FF ETF markets), World Bank (in the NAETF-Gold ETF markets) and the Fiduciary authorities (in the SDR Gold-Gold ETF operations) ensured that the strategy took off the ground immediately upon launch. The economic incentives centred around the rents accruing from the rounds of fusion licence auctions and NAETFs, the pricing of nuclear power to the industry, and the competitive impacts of the availability of cheaper, cleaner energy alternative for production and consumption, and consequently, the growth opportunities in the economy. The enhancement in productivity, due lower energy prices and the consequent inter-factor substitution, induced 2nd round effects that improved the allocation and efficiency of capital, material and labor in the economy.
……………
The born-again Nobel-Scientist trudged back to his ‘lab’ early Sunday morn. (Wasn’t it strange scientists carried their lab routine to their Sabbatical too?). No, not the lab 200m below the surface, but a villa with a view of the oceans on the sparsely-populated island. The ‘Nobel-Senor’ had since changed tracks to let those worthy behind him seek their ‘moment of glory’. For his Sabbatical, he preferred to dwell on the societal impacts of nuclear energy. Filling his lungs with the cool ocean wind interlaced with the aroma from his coffee cup, the Nobel-senor took his eyes of the wind-swept waves to read the Sustainability Strategy document that a ‘Thinktank Fellow’ had emailed him.

“Thinktank Fellows? Is that where Environmental Judges find refuge these days?” Reigning in his wandering thoughts, the Senor perused the document..…Hmm,… it was interesting, enlightening, and even up his newly chosen path. But did they appreciate how easy it was to exploit the strategy should the UIWI be subverted from within and lose control to the mega geo-political counter-strategies of those super-wealthy and politically powerful? Why, even a physicist could pick more than a few holes in it. Whose hair-brained idea was the index? How many arguments would it accommodate and how would they be chosen? At what level of disaggregation? Who would attach the weights to the arguments and how? Would those weights be constant parameters over time until ‘utopia’? What if we learnt decades later that the arguments and/or the weights were inappropriate….or that the Index was achieved but with a polarised and skewed set of argument values? Did the dynamic optimization provide for variable discount rates with time? And were the strategies and predicted outcomes robust to them? (or, was that too assumed equal the ‘expected long-run appreciation in gold prices!’)? Moving on to other concerns, wouldn’t auctioning fusion licences in a world with large wealth differences across nations concentrate them in developed nations with the resources to outbid lesser nations (Or, did the SDR Gold financing correct the imbalance)? How much would the bids at the Fusion auctions fall if the ‘PuoP’ units went ‘peeee’? Did the Judges realize that a half-hearted start to the strategy that excluded the Recycling and Insurance modules could turn the Sustainability Fund in to a milking pot for the Energy and Resource Barons? And what if the IAEA and the IEA colluded to keep carbon permit prices and FL auction bids high (and found friends in ‘subsidy-Inflation leaches’ who multiplied their ill-gained wealth in the arbitrage between bonds, equities and currencies.)? Who would pay the price? Not the millions of NAETF investors? Wasn’t the diversion of subsidies to developing economies a thinly-disguised policy to induce nations to irreversibly choose a carbon-intensive economy? …and pressure the UIWI in to adopting the ‘equity path’ to Sustainability? Didn’t the Reserve buyback scheme amount to enriching those who had already pillaged the environment for private gain…and offer them the opportunity to re-start yet another race to riches? And though he was a stranger to Environmental economics, wouldn’t a rise in passive values for the environment as society turned wealthier, affect the capitalized base of NAETFs? Perhaps these issues had been anticipated? Then again, perhaps not. A Sunday morning ‘missive’ from a Nuclear physicist to a ‘Tinkduck Judge’ would not be amiss, would it?

Dear Dr Judge,
……….

The Judges hoped that the closed-finance, endogenously-solving system they had established would provide the necessary impetus to fast forward global sustainability in a just and transparent manner, and provide a smooth transition to a low carbon, recycling-intensive, fusion-powered future even while paying away the cumulated nuclear debt. They commended the SDR-monetization – Sustainability bond strategy as a generic approach to solve other causes confronting humanity beyond the retirement of nuclear debt. 

As the ‘heptagonal heart’ beat its HFT rhythm between the ripping-unripping of SDR Gold and Gold ETFs, it pushed the life blood of sustainability through the various economic and environmental systems of the human society, turning them cleaner and more efficient, and in harmony with nature. And as the Judges retreated late afternoon from the review of their Sustainability strategy, their elderly ‘patriarch’ with failing vision wondered at the play of colors before his eyes.

Hadn’t the Earth taken on a decidedly greenish-golden hue today?