Regulatory Reform, or………Wreck you Sooner than Later Reform?
Ganga Prasad Rao
Energy, Environmental and Mineral Economist
gprasadrao@hotmail.com
gangaprasad.rao@gmail.com
Disclaimer: The author makes no claims to factuality of the contents, or the outcomes of designs elaborated in this column.
In the short-run, CRRSNA endowed with a $IPN exchanged for a RIPN, anticipates a knee-jerk reaction by a disappointed global-CC industry that takes the form of a coordinated and broad-based, if not surprise withdrawal from the nation's capital markets causing it to crash and the R to falter. It monetizes a tranche of $IPNs into two currencies R and $, and two gold-backed capital, RGETF and $GETF (the former hedges against the $, and the latter against the R), endows the SWF with R and $GETF, and the RP with an equivalent sum of $ and RGETFs, such that the internal exchange rate between the two currencies is equal the external SR FX. Pre-crisis and consistent with its anticipation and strategies, the SWF sells $-GETFs to its partner, in return for $, a Buy option on a weak $, and a Sell option on a strong R. The RP, on its part, promptly converts a part of the $GETF to R. This conversion obtains it a '$-Equal-MNC A' benchmark that it leverages to re-convert R back to $ and its CC-R equivalent, RSETF (thus, and in a sense, forcing the regulatory reform to be par-international, or limiting the re-conversion to the extent it is). Into the crisis, the SWF sells its $ to shore up the R at its weakest while the Ruling party exchanges its residual holdings of the R post the RSETF purchase. It holds on to its residual $-GETFs that appreciate both for reasons of gold being a safe haven, and the appreciating $ (The R-GETFs barely hold their own due counter movements between the currency and the asset class). Post-crisis, the SWF reverses its pre-crisis move by selling R upon the triggering of the Buy on the weak $, and/or, the Sell on the strong R, to buy into $-GETFs, while the Ruling party finds it opportune to harvest the gains in its residual holdings of $-GETFs and moves out into $ that it may, at its convenience, convert to R with its Sell and Buy options. Thus conceived, the two entities anticipate, hedge and overcome collusive regulatory strategies of the global CC Business, inure regulatory negotiations, force a global efficiency benchmark on the regulatory process, and bring stability to the Nation's capital market and currency in the short-run.
Ganga Prasad Rao
Energy, Environmental and Mineral Economist
gprasadrao@hotmail.com
gangaprasad.rao@gmail.com
Disclaimer: The author makes no claims to factuality of the contents, or the outcomes of designs elaborated in this column.
Regulatory Reform is an oft-heard cliche in political circles, and among economists,
investors and bankers. (One almost immediately suspects a conspiracy amongst
them...or, is that being too intrusive?) Textbook regulatory reform is all
about enhancing the efficiency of regulations - existing, under revision,
proposed, and prospective, of maximizing net benefits, ie, incremental benefits
net of incremental costs, about internalizing externalities - non-pecuniary and
pecuniary, and reducing policy uncertainty. But reality is as much distanced
from theory as politics is from truth. Regulatory reform has turned in to a
catch-phrase, even a catch-all for unholy intentions of PV-capitalists, whether
within the nation, or without.
Before unraveling the intrigue around it, lets first put regulatory
reform in perspective. Regulations are necessitated for a myriad reasons: from
defining the legal framework for initiating business, and the boundaries for
conducting business with the Government, competitors and the general public,
delineating the rules by which business in multi-lateral trade contexts, to
oversee, monitor and enforce ethics in financial commons, and in such
contentious areas as IPRs, or, to assert property rights, particularly
concerning the environment and the safety & health of the public. Other
motivators of regulatory reform include revisions and amendments to international
multi-lateral agreements, streamlining with international practices and
standard, especially if that is accompanied with enhanced access to
international resources, advances in technology and concomitant changes in
public risk, political and policy advances, new discoveries, changing social
preferences, catastrophic-events -whether natural or anthropogenic, as
reactions to court fiats and interpretations, regulatory rulings, and even
opportunistic contexts such as bilateral (hedge) funding. Paradoxically, regulations
are a two-edged sword; they are deemed onerous with repetitive amendments and
revisions that increase the burden of compliance on both sides of the
Government-Business divide, and thus the cost of administering regulations and
doing business, but they are also sought by businesses for varied reasons,
extending from protection of markets and prices from internal- and trade-
competition, to avoid business and policy/unforeseen risks in the present and
of the future, to the exploitation of real and strategic opportunities
presented by macro-economic, political, technological, or transitory events.
From this angle, regulatory reform serves as a channel, a medium, a bridge that
permits businesses to be in continuous touch with the Government, and seek reforms/amendments
that, both, insure them from costly risks and positions them to exploit profit
opportunities.
Stakeholders in reform negotiations are buffeted by various pressures -
some that would induce them to cooperate, others compete, and yet others,
strategically accommodate either in bilateral, or multi-lateral contexts.
Cooperative reforms are often 'patriotic' and concern domestic businesses
seeking trade-protective and non-competitive advantages. Strategic rulemaking
is the norm, and is exploited by governments of different leanings and foreign
entities who may leverage their
antipodal niches across the Nation:ROW divide as polar hedges in
financial markets to their advantage. Such reform is guided by strengths and
weaknesses, opportunities and threats, anticipatory strategic moves, and
literally, a 'give-end-take' attitude. In an adversarial context - whether real
or stage-managed, both sides predictably stone-wall each other, and resort to
legal challenges that delay reforms, potentially delaying the introduction of
superior technology, and extending the life of an inefficient and
privately-enriching obsolete technology, regulation or rule. Unlike the
adversarial context in which partisan interests sub-optimize the social pie,
cooperative and strategic regulatory reforms have the potential to maximize
social FV gain, albeit if participants negotiate ethically, without corrupt
intents.
Regulations are measured in various dimensions - efficiency: static and
dynamic, social-, environmental-, economic cost and benefits, transactions
costs, but less overtly, their impact on political fortunes and indeed, the
capital markets. Every regulation, every amendment, every revision has its
winners and losers among stakeholders who are hedged politically and financially.
In fact, much of the lobbying budget owes to attempts by business stakeholders
- small, groups, and large, and who sponsor elections, joint
government-business initiatives, public events and leverage social media, to
seek amendments, inclusions and exclusions, the opening or closing of loopholes
that either pre-empt a private risk, or open an opportunity for concentrated
private gain. Despite strategic cooperation, the Government and Business have
long been at odds with each other in matters regulatory. This owes its origin
to the competitive nature of businesses that induce firms to perpetually cut
costs, whether by holding wages down, skimping on ESH-expenditures, or ignoring
their CSR obligations, and in their opposite, the Government's efforts to
'left' the ship by seeking employment growth, wages and lifestyle enhancements
and social security. Hostility between the Government and Industry,
predictably, exacerbates in Left-leaning and Centrist regimes that pursue a
path of compromise, accommodate sensitivities on both sides of the issue and
seek to sustain economic growth, protect the livelihood and the lifestyles of
people, tighten ESH standards, and safeguard the environment. On the other
hand, Mercantilist and right-leaning governments (beyond Majoritarian
multi-party democracy, weak coalition governments, and 'competitive
federalism'), abet an unbalanced, populist, nominal, PV-hastening regulatory
regime, the gains from which are disproportionately usurped by empowered party
men, 'in-the-know' corrupt bureaucrats, businesses and investor community.
Thus, and far from the economist's ideal of a vehicle to enhance efficiency
incrementally, regulatory reform sub-serves a strategy pursued by the two sides
that either obtain them the approval of the masses as consistent with electoral
mandates, the nature of the government, and indeed, the macro economic hedges,
and/or, profits at the bourses. Such strategic regulatory reform is likely
deeply mired in conflicts of interest on both sides – conflicts that impinge on
democratic representation, cross-sectional and inter temporal efficiency, trade
fair play, financial prudence, legal
diligence on one hand, and upon competition, ESH/labor-relations and
Corporate social responsibilities on the other.
To better comprehend the context within which regulatory strategies
evolve, let us examine the impact of
CC-Trade and the consequent globalization of economic activity. Globalization
and trade that took off with the frenetic pace of synergistic developments in
Finance and IT, brought the bourgeoisie, even the proletariat in every corner
of the world face-to-face with the realities of global competition,
opportunities and risks. Changes in risks, opportunities and incentives
associated with existing or new technologies, inventions and discoveries are
magnified by the global reach of the CC-economy, the global, multilateral
competition for CC-capital and -technology, and the domestic opportunities
offered by friendly or strategic political parties. In this context of
globally-magnified stakes, regulatory reform induces anticipatory strategic
moves by the CC-Industry (and political parties) to secure prospective rents
and avert anticipated losses. Political contributions and the funding of
electoral candidates is one such strategy that pays off handsomely. Such
contributions facilitate access to legislators (and bureaucrats) and ensures
the Government is receptive to their interpretations, claims and proposals
(regardless of actual election outcomes). Given PV-incentives that face
businesses are mirrored in political parties and the Government - the electoral
competition for votes in majoritarian elections only heightening those
tendencies, regulatory reform, whether cooperative or strategic, is often a
thinly-veiled camouflage for mutually PV-aggrandizing policy reform. Whether
induced by competitive threat or opportunism, regulatory reform has turned in
to an overtly public, yet obfuscated and camouflaged strategy to PV-aggrandize
regulatory stakeholders by leveraging financial markets to monetize
opportunities that the markets would otherwise not offer. This extends from
introducing unsustainable and non-competitive technologies, regulatory policies
with loopholes, options and alternatives that would normally not be permitted
or considered, modifying terms of trade to favor FV-reducing options for the
PV-gains that accrue private parties, delaying or denying discoveries and
innovations, permitting unsustainable subsidies, politically-motivated
interventions in such matters as competition, the timing of approvals, issue
and renewal of licenses, even IPOs, tariff-setting and revisions, and
litigation, to name a few. These strategies typically reduce a societal future
by hastening it, motivate instruments that concentrate 'capital market-alpha
gains' in political hands and corporate entities, and distribute costs amongst
a large group across space and time in a manner that makes them invisible,
imperceptible and seemingly of little consequence, if not incognizable (thus
engendering an inter-temporal private-public externality in the sense that
stakeholders who would benefit are pro-actively induced to seek such design,
and the affected public largely unaware or unable to respond effectively. NGOs,
claiming to represent the public, are oftentimes party to the design). Examples
abound: from arms purchases, pricing 'subsidized' pharmaceuticals, auctioning
of property rights and their cancellation, doctored PPAs and
exploration-contracts to alter sectoral fuel-choice and trade competition that
unbalance the playing-field, to land acquisition, permitting foreign investment
& competition, and regulations governing infrastructure investments.
Despite their potential impact upon global environmental and labor market
impacts, each has the potential to rake in a PV 100% in the capital markets,
and together they represent a very real and perpetual challenge to long-term
sustainability of the nation, even the society. Thus, in Populist-PV-Nominal
regimes, the incentives and motivations that underlie regulatory reform are
quite often to the opposite of the long-run social good.
On a more sedate note, most CC-Technology is Capital-intensive,
involving plant and equipment that
necessitate large, upfront investment, that can only be recovered across
decades. Given governments last only a few years, and both, political parties
and voters, have short memory and are notoriously fickle, businesses must
devise a means to ensure their profitability beyond mere survival. It is in
this context that regulatory reform turns significant; in fact reforms take on strategic hues that seem more
like 'BizAssurance'. 'BizAssurance' addresses uncertainty in input, output and
factor markets, a key objective of reform initiatives and government-business
negotiations, by seeking deals with institutions, organizations and entities
that obtain those ends. To start with, the CC-Business identifies significant
political- and 'cause-enemies', approaches the former to take a position
opposite the latter, and further ensures they will react in a predictable and
strategic manner in certain contexts and contingencies. Next, it makes
fiduciary monetary deals with 'permanent' government institutions, such as the
RBI, with whom it registers its budgetary support lines and FDI keys in return
for 'Taxassurance' (AMT) and 'FXAssurance-FX Bands' (the latter as determined
by the bounds of FX-interpretation on the multi-decadal compacts around
IPN-exchanges between friendly nations. IPNs represent macro-prudential,
fiduciary instruments deposited with a friendly nation meant to serve as an
inter-temporal counterweight that stabilizes the nation's PV economy from
international currency market-, trade- and economic- perturberances). Beyond
these assurances, the CC-Business
leverages its access to the Lower House to ensure certain favorable
legislative outcomes on the floor of the House; it exploits the Parliamentary
Opposition to communicate with regulators and obtains their tacit agreement
concerning competition, prices/terms of trade and such regulatory issues as
exit, labor compensations, etc; it
anticipates judicial and regulatory challenges triggered by (nominally)
'unpatriotic (cause-)enemies', by leveraging the access the Upper House has to
the Supreme Court, to pre-negotiate 'sector-sustainable administrative
compacts' with the school of Judges (that implicitly enforces a 'Dionysus I
Pareto') in return for supporting their EO-Causes. Together, these strategies,
that account for a significant share of 'transactions costs' borne by the group
of firms, sector or the mercantilist nation, obtain a degree of market- and
inter-temporal certainty for CC-Business that permit it to commit to, and
undertake massive and multi-decadal investments in a foreign nation.
The dominance of extant technology over the yet-unborn future
technology by such means as subsidies, and the delay or suppression of superior
technologies, is evident in PV-Capital markets, that, ever in search of
expanded profits, incentivize the intensive exploitation of existing, low
private-cost technologies that reduce the futures of a dispersed group. To
relate an example, dam-building and
hydro-power generation capability is being exploited along the Mekong river to
secure profits for owners of conventional technology while reducing natural
assets, and undercutting the support provided to its people by
intergenerational natural resources of the region. (Unsustainable PV-hastening, by reducing the future of a large group,
breaks into the personal intergenerational wealth spheres of members belonging
to future generations, especially if that hastening involves the Commons and
Natural resources. Incidentally, one would expect that the nature of capital
employed by the firm PV-hastening its profits at the bourses, or via an IPO,
would also matter. Firms with EO/Social capital, whose revenues and gains are
distributed broadly in the public, likely cause less damage to the Social-FV
than firms with ZS-Competition capital that would rather enrich themselves
albeit for the price of a smaller and unbalanced societal future. One could
further assert that should an unsustainable hastening enrich the EO-capital
endowed Government, it triggers vice and slavery obligations to restore social
sustainability; else if that hastening is enriching to ZS-capitalists, it
enforces an FV-reducing zero-sum on the society, even its customers, in a
time-horizon not uncorrelated with the unattained EPS growth projected for the
PV-hastening. Thus, IPOs for CC-ZS capital are best priced at lower than market
PE multiples for the same EPS-growth, else limited to the low-growth,
low-margin, sub-aural sectors of the economy).
It is
pertinent to make two additional points. First, the hastening of a future
stream of profits to the present engenders PV-Externalities and FV-Damages, the
extent of which depends on the nature of production and consumption technology.
Should technology be safe, efficient and closed-cycle, the hastening is likely
to cause minimal impacts, and the future
translated to the present in about as-is condition; else, the hastening could
substantially reduce the quality of life bestowed a future generation (the
former represents a low-discount rate regime; the latter a high, implying that
PV-hastening protects and captures most of the potential future in the case of
the former, and reduces it significantly in the latter). Second, and whereas
theoretically, the full costs and benefits of regulations are social, MNCs,
domestic businesses and commercial interests (and political parties ahead of
electoral duels) have an incentive to pursue only those opportunities
associated with concentrated private profits; the same is noticeably lacking
among members of the public who face a very real, if distributed regulatory
impact across space and time, but are individually oblivious to it. (This
incentive externality that owes its origins to under- or misperceived impacts,
and to individually-insurmountable transactions costs shrinks to the extent
such causes are taken up by environmental organizations and NGOs.) Further, and
since private costs and benefits perceived by the industry/niche-polarized
political parties do not dovetail with social costs and benefits, the same will
not be internalized in their strategies and decisions, thus engendering potential
externalities in various spheres of the society – ESH, social, monetary,
governance, gender, even ethical and moral. This is particularly true in a
Populist-PV-Nominal society with term- and regime-limited memories,
responsibilities and payoffs. In such contexts, those stakeholders with access
to resources, power and authority, who might benefit in a concentrated manner,
have an asymmetric incentive to strategize, conspire/collude, deal or otherwise
obfuscate/offer largesse and obtain their PV-hastened benefits to the detriment
of the present and future society.
Beyond these externalities, the confluence of the
Populist-PV-Nominal regime, and PV-centered monetary policies and financial
markets dominated by '(Mars ZS) CC Competition' capital imply there exist (even
for MNCs) large economic rents from policy intervention, such as legislating
rules and regulations involving restraint of competition, strategic amendments
to/ timing of innovation, taxes, government-protected subsidized markets, etc.
One is not entirely amiss to claim that it is with these motivations that MNCs and
foreign trade entities seek parleys with the government of the day, or
anticipate electoral contributions with. Infact, political parties
backed by electoral mandate from indiligent citizens, and opportunistic
businesses with deep, globally-sourced pockets, are perversely empowered to
seek loopholes, exceptions, and amendments to existing rules and proposed
regulations that dovetail in to their capabilities, niche, opportunistic business
plans, and that leverage their global political-, financial-, economic reach
and technological prowess. Regulatory reform, at its worst, could then well be
a systematic and repetitive exploitation of societal FV-wealth by the very
governments and businesses supposed to sustain and grow it. It is in this context that one seeks an answer as to how
political parties, the government or other regulatory stakeholders, distinguish
the honest reform proposals made by (foreign) entrepreneurs leveraging their expertise and foresight, and
understandably ‘patriotic’ national trade interests, from those backed by
technology newts and strategy experts conspiring with shady offshore financial
entities who buy their way in to political parties and platforms, leverage their
subscription to the global net of academic experts and professional
consultants, exploit their political and financial influence and strategically
manipulate rule-making and regulations that serve their private ends and very
partisan interests? Wouldn’t these grey-entities exploit coalition politics,
and competition for foreign investments across jurisdictions, to scoop-away the
PV ice-cream of economic rents by their strategic introduction of unproven
technology, albeit camouflaged in regulatory reform? And, more to the point,
how should public institutions
anticipate such manipulative intents? Is Regulatory Reform merely the legal
fig-leaf to hide behind-the-scenes consultations and negotiations – some
regulatory, some political, some ostensibly patriotic and others, strategic
diplomacy - that open the door to FV-compromising PV-aggrandizement by members of ruling party? If so, how
would one with a long-social perspective internalize the perverse incentives that pervade in these
interactions? To recognize that a problem – geographically-dispersed,
politically-managed, overt, yet camouflaged and less-perceptible – exists, is
but a beginning; one must persevere to find a credible and transparent solution
to it.
Let us frame the issue as an outcome from the confluence of
PV-enriching incentives on both sides, ie, on one side the Populist-PV-Nominal
Party/Government answerable to its electoral mandate, and on the other,
Businesses competing in the PV-ZS capitalist markets. On one hand, it is
arguably a case of Agency problem - one in which a government ostensibly
elected 'by the people, of the people, for the people' camouflages its
corrupt-intentions in the impatience of the public for a fulfilling
PV-lifestyle, to compartmentalize and appease them in the present albeit
reducing their group-future. Simultaneously, and on the other, businesses must
inevitably answer to investor- and shareholder pressures in Capital-markets
(the return threshold), and that implies a preference for PV-profit maximizing
strategies. Further, the Ruling realize that reform-seeking MNCs have
alternative investment destinations should the nation cold-shoulder their
reform initiatives (ie, the CC-Opportunity cost) and could well re-direct its
not-insignificant capital to more receptive and accommodating nations. These
incentives converge to induce both sides to meet half-way, albeit with
strategic, if not unethical intents.
While there could potentially be many answers to the conundrum - social
and political, in particular - this column seeks a solution in the very
instruments that serve as the medium of PV-aggrandizement, ie, Finance and
capital markets. The challenge is to devise measures that indicate the extent
to which potential social FV-gains are reduced, hastened and PV-concentrated in
private hands, and parallely, costs distributed amongst the masses across space
and time. Within adversarial and corrupt-cooperative contexts, and given the
conflicts of interests that are inherent to regulatory reform, it is best a
neutral entity, with as much concern for the present as for the future, such as
(in India), the 'CAG-RBI-Rajya Sabha-Niti Ayog'
(CRRSNA), anticipate such mal-incentives and impacts, and design
objective and foresighted instruments to negate them, cover for residual
pecuniary and non-pecuniary impacts, and improve upon reform proposals
continually. Additionally, the CRRSNA would like to design appropriate hedges
that, both inure the long-run future of the nation and position it strategically
in subsequent rounds of regulatory reform. Toward the first objective, the
CRRSNA anticipates regulatory moves by the two entities: the Government/Ruling
Party representing citizens and endowed with EO capital and property rights to
natural resources and the Commons, and technology-empowered Businesses, with
CC- or Trade-capital. It pre-supposes the Ruling party will seek to aggrandize
from PV-enriching pareto-, or perverse- regulatory reforms that are in
consonance with its Populist-PV-Nominal agenda, and that it could legislate
through its Government in cooperation or connivance with domestic businesses
and MNCs. It also rationally expects the Ruling party to prefer reforms that
attract lower capital-cost FDI, and those that are likely to aggrandize it
discreetly post it's tenure. Further, it also presumes Businesses, fearing
outflow of capital from other sectors into the 'reformed' sector, would only
permit reforms in periods of loose monetary policy regimes and during equity-bull runs when broad-based capital
inflow pre-empts lop-sided, or zero-sum gains in sectoral equity valuation.
Toward the second objective, the CRRSNA seeks a long monetary strategy
that anticipates and pre-empts
significant losses to the nation's future.
Toward fulfilling these objectives, CRRSNA anticipates successful
reform-hastened short-run profits, or failed reform-triggered losses in the
regulated sector by recommending the Sovereign Wealth Fund, SWF, and the Ruling
party, RP, simultaneously execute CRRSNA-sponsored, paired, Buy- and Sell-
'polar Half-options' in the Sectoral ETF. These paired, mirror-options permit
opposite bets upon the post-reform SETF NAV, thus facilitating the SWF and RP
to 'square' the option-facilitated trades post reform negotiations. This strategy
forces a post-reform and post-term, CRRSNA-monitored reconciliation, enabling
the 'permanent' SWF to 'compensate' the 'temporary' Government discretely for
its role in the reform process (such as in the cover of 'cricket frenzy',
'border skirmishes' or various orchestrated agitations). Simultaneously, and
while yet in the midst of reform negotiations, it recommends hedging potential
negative FX-reactions to regulatory negotiations from the global CC-Business,
such as a swift and broad-based withdrawal from capital markets of the nation,
and in to other alternatives such as dollar-denominated GETFs and/or more
inviting global destinations, by suggesting an internal arrangement between the
SWF and the Ruling party. This arrangement pre-supposes the SWF and the Ruling
party have opposite regulatory stakes: the SWF focused on the Long,
specifically, the strength of the Rupee and the health of the capital market,
and the Ruling party, with dual stakes as apparent in its preference for
Sectoral-ETFs in the short, and on the $ in the Long.
Costs of Unsuccessful-
and Benefits of Successful Regulatory Reform
COSTS
|
COSTS
|
BENEFITS
|
BENEFITS
|
|
SR
|
LR
|
SR
|
LR
|
|
Capital flight,
Squandered SR reform rents
|
Weaker Currency, Social
Inequity, Economic inefficiency
|
Gain in Sectoral
efficiency; Stronger capital market
|
Stronger Currency
|
Government/
Ruling Party
|
Lobbying costs,
Electoral contributions
|
Lost credibility
|
Stronger Equity market
|
CC Efficiency rents
|
CC Business
|
Option-based hedging to
anticipate collusive regulatory strategist
CRRSNA
leverages $IPN and issues SWF with
(R, $GETFs)
SWFR:RP$ FX at SR market equilibrium
|
CRRSNA leverages
$IPN and issues Ruling Party with (RGETFs, $)
SWFR:RP$ FX at SR market equilibrium
|
Endowment @t0
|
Convert $GETFs to $
(plus Buy option on weak $ and Sell on strong R) until SWFR:RP$ FX
equilibrates with Long FX between two IPN-exchanging nations.
|
Sell $ for $GETFs (plus
Buy option on weak R and Sell option
on strong $). Convert $GETF to R
(plus '$ Equal-MNC A' investment benchmark). Exploit benchmark marginally to
partially convert R to $ and RSETFs.
|
Pre- crisis
|
Shore up R upon the triggering of the Sell on
strong $.
|
Sell crisis-weakened
Rupee for strong $
|
Into the crisis
|
Sell R for $ upon triggering of the Buy
option on weak $;
Convert $ to $GETFs
until FX volatility subsides and a new SR FX equilibrium is established.
|
Trigger Buy on strong R from SWF for $; Convert exchanged R to RGETFs or $
consistent with position in polar SETFs.
|
Post-crisis
|
These short-run option-hedges do not anticipate the long-run impacts of
PV-ZS-FV regulatory reform that are injurious to the nation. The long hedges
must cover for the expected weakening of the nation's currency due dubious
reform intents, inefficient technology- and policy-environment. (When the PV-FV imbalance is caused by a
large IPO entering the capital market, an 'IPO Perpetuity Line-FV
Sustainability key', offered the new entrant in lieu of its IPO proceeds, might
attenuate the FV-impacts of PV-hastening, as might supporting a
'Gold-opposite-House Perpetuity pyramid' flanked by Commons Bonds and
Infrastructure/Safety-Health, ISH, Bonds that obtain the necessary
PV-counterweight to the FV-reducing impacts of PV-hastening). But that
would necessitate a simple and credible measure of long FX that reflects the
impact of FV-reducing 'regulatory reform'. Toward such an instrument, consider
Currency Long-Forwards (positioned opposite long Bonds?) upon CRRSNA-sponsored
International Promissory Note, IPNs. The FV, nominal face-value of the IPN
implies a reference FX for currency long-forwards; it must be pegged to a
defensible measure of the FV-financial/economic state of the IPN-issuing
nation. To avoid issuing IPNs exclusively linked to a PV-Nominal construct such
as is the GDP, one could issue and calibrate them to the projected appreciation
of, or decrement to an index (LGDPBND) that is a weighted average of projected
annual average growth rate of nominal Long GDP and nominal annual returns to
long Bonds of the same 'tenure', with expected average long-term inflation rate
as the weight, such that higher the inflation rate, the more weight assigned to
Bonds in the computation of the index, lower its value, lower the expected IPN
worth, and weaker the currency long-forward; the presumption being that high
inflation rates, despite their correlation with GDP growth, are FV-reducing (Figure). A LGDPBND-indexed
IPN-validation construct would measure and benchmark the impacts of current
policy/reform decisions on the future. So designed, the long-FX-forward, linked
to real time IPN FV-valuation, would rise with the expectation of a sustainable
expansion in the nation's future, and fall otherwise, thus offering an
effective, market-anticipated, readily-observable and regularly-updated, public
instrument to measure regulatory reform proposals potentially associated with
irreversible, inter-temporal impacts. The CRRSNA would leverage this instrument
to evaluate and calibrate competing proposals for regulatory reform and suggest
to the SWF and RP, both, a cardinal ranking and inter-temporal spacing of the
reform proposals, and appropriate instruments to secure gains and hedge losses.
Endowed with an appropriate instrument to price the long FX, consider
an inter-temporal (t0-t1), half-pareto currency hedge between two friendly
nations, A and B, the latter evaluating policy- and reform proposals involving
entry of foreign technology. Country-B hedges its R by offering a R-IPN in
exchange for a $1B IPN from Country-A. The issued terminal-value of the R-IPN, implies a significantly weaker
currency than what its current FX@t0 would indicate (Country-A might interpret
the implicit FX@t1 differently from
Country-B, thus causing into existence a Long FX-Band), and permits Country-A
to issue bonds, if not $ currency on it. Emboldened with the $1B IPN hedge, Country-B
accepts certain reform-facilitated foreign technologies. Should the technology
and the reform enhance efficiency and grow the nation, the R would appreciate over the period t0 - t1, the LGDPBND index and
the long FX holds its ground, and the R-IPN
invalidated by the SWF for the return of $1B IPN. However, should the
technology and the policy-reform fail, reduce the nation's future, and
consequently, the nation's currency plunge to beyond the FX for which the R-IPN was issued, Country-B permits
Country-A its rights to the R-IPN and monetizes the $-IPN to $ (even
prematurely, ie, before t1), and thus averts a dramatic loss to the nation's
future.
To illustrate with an example, consider armaments offered a nation at
what seems a beneficial deal with 'kickbacks' and commissions, and even a PV-aggrandizing
bull-run in the market, but that might yet engender a war in a not-too-distant
future period opaque to the stock markets and beyond the term of the present
government. This dastardly PV-ZS-FV strategy, from beyond the shores, might not
be unacceptable to political parties hedged for border disputes with
neighbouring nations, and with the investor constituency in the capital market.
It would seemingly bring prosperity in the short-run as measured by
conventional PV-measures of economic activity and wealth, but the same would
set off alarms in the upper echelons of the planners and long-investors by
projecting a significantly weaker currency in the long, due the physical or
financial internalization of the probability of a debilitating war reflected in
lower expected IPN worth. Thus, a nation such as India, hedged in an
IPN-exchange with the US for an FX of 80:1 in 2025, might default on it should
an Arms deal spark a war with a neighbouring nation, due which the equity
markets crash and its currency slip to 120. In such a context, the nation, responding to a weakening of the long
FX post executing the Arms deal, might well seek to pre-empt that future by
hedging between peace and diplomacy. Further, the CRRSNA might anticipate and
strategize around reform-engendered appreciation and depreciation to the
nation's currency. Thus, it might recommend that an expected FV-gain be secured
in Realty sectoral-ETFs, and that a feared loss be anticipatorily hedged and
reduced in FX volatility prior to t1 – volatility that offers the opportunity
to partially monetize the $-IPN, and which transitions the FX-market to a new
equilibrium representing a 'permanently' weaker domestic currency.
Between the SETF-cum-GETF R-$
hedges in the short-run, and the IPN-hedge-exchange in the Long, an independent
entity, such as the CRRSNA, would have sufficient data and variables to
construct measures that indicate the extent to which a Government or a Ruling
Party 'lurches' and/or 'stoops' - the former representing the extent it would
lean to the right to aggrandize a few, and the latter the extent to which it
would compromise the nation toward its private enrichment. Let us delve on
those measures.
The PV-concentration of reform-rents, representing a primary objective
of reform efforts, could be measured by expected gains to the regulated-sector
ETF relative the gains (losses) in the broader market - an easy to measure
ratio - whereas the CSTS distribution of costs associated with the reform -
macro-impacts such as employment, income and FX effects, or policy-delay,
pecuniary impacts, mass-, involuntary social disenfranchisement and dislocation
- must be characterized by its
magnitude, the size of the domain across which it is distributed, and the
length of the interval over which the costs have been spread (and gains
'hastened'). Thus, if private benefits in the form of expected sectoral gains,
incremental to baseline 'no-reform' returns, were x%, incremental broader
market gains or losses, Y%, so that x/Y indicated the incremental concentration
of private 'benefits' from 'alpha-conducive reform' ; if inter-temporal social
costs were C, the breadth of the domain, D, (as measured by the fraction
of population affected, and/or the
cumulative percent/percentile impacted) and interval I, so that the
CSTS-distributed costs took the form C/(D*I) - a variable that'd correlate with
public perception and cognizance of that impact, then the 'Regulatory Lurch
Factor', RLF, an indicator of private gain/alpha-concentration relative cost distribution
and obfuscation, would, tentatively, be expressed as x/Y / C/(D*I), or
x*(D*I)/Y*C. In the general case, an increase in the RLF ratio above, sought by
reform-sponsors, would imply a lurch to the Right that aggrandizes a few,
against the distributed, but imperceptible and hence
cognizance/salience-escaping pain/loss suffered by masses across space and
time.
As concerns the Regulatory Stoop Factor, RSF, the same may be obtained
as the ratio of gains that accrue the Government and the Ruling party in the
near term, to the losses that burden the nation in the Long. Denoting GRPGAIN
as the dollar-equivalent of short-term gains accruing to the RP and the SWF
post-settlement of the SETF Buy and Sell trades initiated with option-bets, the
incremental weakening of the nation's long FX due inefficient PV-hastening by
(-ve)DLTAFX, and the decremental loss to the nation's long GDP by (-ve)DLTAGDP,
the RSF may be expressed simply as GRPGAIN/-(DLTAFX*DLTAGDP), such that the
more FV-reducing the PV-hastening, the more negative would be the computed RSF
ratio. Unethical Ruling Parties as well as alpha-seeking capitalists would seek
their objectives and ends by maximizing RLF and minimizing the RSF. Between the
Lurch factor and the Stoop factor,
independent entities, in particular the CRRSNA, would be endowed with the means
to evaluate the extent of political bias in the incessant waves of regulatory
reforms, and guide the nation thru a path of mutual PV-accommodation and
FV-social sustainability, to bring about a more equitable and efficient
innovation- and technology-conducive society.
Having outlined issues that stem from the confluence of PV-capitalism
and populist paradigms, it is noteworthy that as populations rise, subsidies
turn more unsustainable, the pressures to pursue a Populist-PV-Nominal paradigm
become more urgent. PV-hastening, within such context, could force subsequent
generations and governments to necessarily follow the Nominal-Right path, lest
there be an exacerbation of social inequity and inter-temporal monetary
stability, in the process, irreversibly changing the character of the society
and the futures of its people. Thus, regulatory-reform engendered PV-hastening
must be tempered with prudent FV-PV balancing that goes beyond financial
options and hedges to the protection of social and natural support systems.
Further, policies that identify and counter the
camouflaged CSTS-distribution of costs associated with perverse reforms,
and incentivize institutions that take pro-active cognizance of such CSTS-cost
obfuscation are indicated, as are financing mechanisms for their public
activities. A final thought: Democracy is ostensibly the rule of the people by
representatives elected to further the interests of the society. And while it
does obtain a quasi-stable society for households to grow, and businesses to
expand in, it is fraught with significant risks of economic and financial
exploitation by concentrated political, financial and technological interests -
some friendly, others not - that transcend the understanding of the
financially-constrained common man deceived into accepting a
nominal-PV-populist government for his survival and livelihood, thus
potentially subverting a fundamental
goal of democracy. It is in the interest of the regulatory community, political
leaders and representatives of the civic society to take cognizance of the
perverse incentives arising from the
interaction of 'democratic', Populist-PV-Nominal politics, and the
ZS-capital-endowed global CC-business, and pro-actively & publicly confront
them, nip the larger social irreversibilities while yet incipient, and assure
the society of a sustainable future.