The GP ‘Macro Bowl O’
Economy !
Ganga Prasad G. Rao
The world over, it is the same humdrum, the same reaction to
the economic crisis that has afflicted nations across the globe. Every economic
contraction, no matter of what origin must be responded to by stimulating the
economy with low interest rates and ‘stimulus funds’. Pump prime an economy
with ‘policies’ that have no credibility, shore up the very banks that caused
the financial crash with their ultra-short trading, even indulge in a privately
enriching market crash despite an obvious conflict of interest …..and when the
economy fails, put your hands up, point your finger at the ‘other guy’, and
walk away with your booty in the melee of a regime change. Macro-politics, my
friend, is an art to master! So, in a world of no alternatives, let’s, for a
change, break all taboos – I mean, academic - and imagine the unimaginable. Let
us motivate a macro-economy with an entirely different rationale. An economy
that does not hide its loot behind austerity programs, an economy that does not
encash policies and regulations even before they are enacted, in fact an
economy that cares, I mean a ….. ‘welfare state’, yes you heard it right, a ‘freebie
economy’. A freebie welfare state when we aren’t able to even half-way support
a subsidy economy? Sure sounds implausible. But ‘miracle’ is a word in the
dictionary, right? So, let’s dare the odds and dream…I mean, read on!
Consider a society comprised of a set of households
maximizing whose aggregate utility is the objective of the Government. Let HC
represent a vector comprising of the entire set of households, and let i
denominate the income-ranked ‘percentile elements’ within. HCi|i=k represents
households in percentile i with income equal an arbitrary percentile, k. P
denotes population, T represents the state of Technology, and Pc, the price of
carbon, is a proxy for the (scarcity value of) the environmental commons. As
the frontier of technology expands and the resource base expands, productivity
increases in the economy, resulting in higher income, savings, wealth and
investment (and a lowering of discount rates) among households. Due the existing
inequity in household income, the expansion of the economy benefits the higher
ranked household, HCi|i>>50 more than it does households HCj|j<<50.
Such economic growth may be expressed as (GDPf| Y^HCi|i>>50 >
Y^HCj|j<<50), where GDPf represent GDP-Efficiency phase, and Y^
represents the change in household income. In other words, income/wealth growth
in the higher percentiles of households far outpaces income growth in the lower
percentiles. Conversely, GDP growth could be ‘equitable’ (denoted by GDPe)
and reduce the disparity in income, ie, (GDPe| Y^HCi>>50
<< Y^HCi<<50). These two phases are not unlike an
elastic rubber band that expands proportionately from a point of origin (a peg/stake)
in the poorest household (GDPf), and one that rebounds in favour of
the poor (GDPe) with the income of richest held constant. In times
of recessions, similar logic holds. In a shrinking economy too, two phases are
possible – an inequitable recession with the poor suffering larger losses than
the rich, and an ‘equitable’ recession with the rich paying the price. In the latter
case, the band, pegged to the poor, shrinks from the rich end, and in the former,
the poor end of the band slides back while the ‘hedged’ rich hold their place
at the far corner. Over time and across the expansionary and contractionary
phases, the rubber band economy moves forward in fits and starts, much like a
worm, occasionally backtracking some, perhaps to ‘straighten’ its path. If that
were all to this 2-phase rubber-band economic paradigm, one would label it a
‘worm hole economy’ and move on to the next jingle on the idiot box.
But, what if we embellished this economy not with a
‘subsidy’, but a ‘freebidy’ that offered free a subset of consumption goods and
services to a subset of households up to a certain monetary amount per period? The
freebie consumption subset would comprise of both essential goods and upscale
‘luxury’ and high-tech goods. Eligibility would be determined by a cut-off
household percentile, HCi|i = z, z being the percentile cut-off determined by a
host of economic, demographic and environmental variables. Predictably, the
percentile cut-off would rise with income and resource base, RB – a variable
that half-proxies for technology as well. Anticipating the impact of the
freebidy scheme on prices and labor supply, as well as a ‘freebie-exploiting
society’, and to accommodate the environment, the percentile cut-offs is
designed to roll back with wage rate, w, the inflation rate, r, the price of
carbon permits, Pc, and with PLsw, the marginal bid for the issue of landfill
permits to private landfill operators in an auction (a proxy for solid waste
fee), and Pop, the Population:
Freebidy Percentile Cut-off, z =
g(PCGDP^, RB^, w^, r, Pc^, PLsw^, Pop^),
where ‘^’ represents percent changes.
The cut-off plays an important role in separating the haves
from have-nots. The latter group are supported economically with freebies - essentials
are doled out up from the bottom percentiles of the household ladder, and luxuries
handed free from the cut-off downwards. As income and the resource base expands
from technology, knowledge enhancements, and reductions in cost of production,
the standard of living and lifestyle expectations undergo revision, and more
goods and services fall either in to the essential or ‘commodity’ category. Concomitantly,
the percentile cut-off increases, consequent to which the ‘freebie subset’
enlarges. In recession, the logic reverses, and the cut-off percentiles fall,
or equivalently, less of the freebie is available to eligible households. The
intention, indeed the hope of this radical proposal, is that by offering
essential or luxury goods and services free to the deserving and future
consumers, the government could keep the economic juggernaut moving across
recessions and depressions without resorting to patently self-deceiving
macro-gimmicks. Thus distributed, economic growth is equity- enhancing; simultaneously,
it enhances/preserves scale economies and permits a rationale for price
discrimination while stimulating demand for luxuries and high tech products in
those who likely to move out of the freebie net and turn future customers.
It doesn’t take an economist to question the financial
sustainability of the proposal, or an environmentalist to question its
environmental sustainability. That a ‘freebidy’ in isolation is unsustainable
unless there is near limitless resource or near zero-cost, environmentally
benign, production technology is well known. But this proposal does not assume
either; it is designed within the confines of ‘closed finance’ so that the freebidy
economy automatically limits itself to what is sustainable. In essence, the
proposal is initiated, dependent and bounded by ‘macro, strategic/hedge money
pots’ that nonetheless serve to allocate and bound expenditures and investments
in the real world. These money pots are in the nature of funds tied to ‘economic
drivers’ - Inflation, Potential GDP (Gap), Solid waste (remediation), and
Product quality – that impact on the nation’s health, and which are anticipated,
staked and hedged by the industry and the government. To this, one could
potentially add random and non-random, natural and anthropogenic ‘phenomena’ such
as wars and communal strife, or earthquakes and monsoons, which too are
anticipated and hedged at the start of a new term.
Toward such a closed, sustainable financial allocation, let
us first recognize the stakes and claims of the Government and the Industry.
Following a win at the hustings with its plank, the Government, cognizant of
its obligations to serve its citizens, aligns its monetary policies along a
targeted Potential GDP which implies a certain M2 Growth and anticipated inflation
rate. In a complementary move, the Industry counts on a certain amount of environmental
obligation (the price (of carbon) of polluting the commons, Pc), and some permitted
environmental damage (Solid Waste, implicitly translating to a prospective pot
of money, SW 2key). The Industry joins the Government in accepting a ‘Service’ obligation
which they split in to boom-cycle and bust-cycle 2keys. The Government, aware
that the potential GDP will likely not be achieved or adhered to, and that its
trend will be interrupted with booms and busts, stakes a boom-time ‘Inflation 2key
Potential GDP 2key’ ‘self-interest’ card, while the Industry pursues a ‘Product
Quality (PQ) Bakey Solid Waste 2key Share’ strategy. The two sides exchange their
respective bakeys, ie, the Government offers to the Industry an Inflation 2key
Bakey, while the Industry does not mind the Government sharing in its SW 2key
Bakey. In Bust, the Industry falls back to ‘Product quality 2key SW 2key Bakey’
and the Government to its Inflation Bakey Potential GDP Gap 2key. The
Government seeks the PQ 2key bakey from the Industry in return for the Potential
GDP Gap 2key Bakey. These funds are then applied by the two sides toward their
freebidy obligations/offers as explained below.
In the context of the reality of macro-cycle involving
growth periods and recessionary phases, due which prices, inventories, and
interest rates cycle up and down, it’d be appropriate, even opportune, to
bifurcate the ‘freebidy’ set of goods two ways: in to Essentials and Luxury,
and in to Durables and Consumables. Such categorization is consistent equity
goals of the government, with the impact of the interest rate cycle on the
demand for durables, the impact of interest rates on durable inventories, and of
those inventories upon prices. The categorization also helps focus funds
specifically to targeted families for targeted outcomes.
BOOM
|
BUST
|
||||||||
ESSENTIAL
|
LUXURY
|
ESSENTIAL
|
LUXURY
|
||||||
Durable
|
Consumable
|
Durable
|
Consumable
|
Durable
|
Consumable
|
Durable
|
Consumable
|
||
BOOM
|
SW 2key Bakey
|
Ind
|
Ind
|
||||||
SW Bakey Share
|
Govt
|
Ind
|
|||||||
Inflation 2key
|
Govt
|
||||||||
Inflation Bakey
|
Ind
|
||||||||
BUST
|
Pot GDP Gap 2key
|
Govt
|
|||||||
Pot GDP Gap Bakey
|
Ind
|
||||||||
PQ 2key
|
Ind
|
||||||||
PQ Bakey
|
Govt
|
In Boom, the Government chooses to discharge the service
obligation; it applies the Service 2key to serve the indigent households down
from the percentile cut-off, while the Industry is too busy minting money to
care about the bakey. In this phase of the economic cycle, the Government and
the Industry share their ill-gotten Inflation and SW 2key bakey with the
indigent. The Government, inherently more caring for the poor than the
Industry, sponsors the free issue of essential-consumables to Household below
the cut-off in a bottom-up fashion until the Inflation 2key pot runs out. The
Industry, always seeking to expand its business and profit from it, offers
‘luxury consumables’ as freebies to those near the ‘income-knee’ (the
percentile cut-off). Between the Government and the Industry, the Inflation pot
and the SW 2key bakey pot obtain some equity gains to the indigent and
prospective lifestyle gains to those at the threshold of crossing the
‘poor-rich threshold’.
In Bust, the Industry takes over the obligation, and sponsors
voluntary organization with the Service 2key to serve the poorest in society. The
Government is too busy with its economic policy-making seeking an end of the
recession, to worry about the bakey. Beyond their service obligation, the Government
and the Industry switch to two other pots: the Potential GDP Gap and the
Product Quality. The industry shares its PQ 2key as durable-consumable freebies
with prospective consumers just below the percentile cut-off. In addition, it
supports those IPOs that support the cause of product quality, energy
efficiency and resource/material conservation. The Government chooses to ‘invest’
the PQ Bakey in essential durables among the poor households at the bottom of
the percentile ladder. It also offers its PGDP Gap 2key to freebidize essential
consumables. In all cases, the allocations by the Government/Industry between essentials
and luxuries and between consumables and durables follow the proportions in
which the 2key and bakey were taken by the two opposing parties.
The function ‘g’, which determines z, the critical freebidy percentile
cut-off variable, and which weights the various socio-economic and demographic
variables, is further calibrated in an accounting sense with the size of the
various money pots involved. As technology advances, more resources are
discovered, and as production turns more efficient – both cost-wise and
environmentally, both Potential GDP and Product Quality money pots expand, the percentile
cut-offs advance higher in to the household income distribution, and the
society turns incrementally a welfare state. Conversely, if inflation rears its
head, if population expands unsustainably, if there is palpable resource
scarcity, or if the environment deteriorates due inefficiency in production, the
percentile cut-off shrinks back, reducing the size of the freebidy pie to what
is sustainable given the money pots on line.
To ensure efficiency in the allocation of freebies, the
administrator of this system issues ‘Durable-‘ and ‘Consumable-Freebie points’
to the target group that, in aggregate, sum up to the available funds. These
points are bankable across time, but are neither exchangeable across type of
good or across recipients. The recipients of the freebie points exchange them for
the various durables and consumables offered in the freebie basket, each priced
in points equal the prevailing market price. This strategy, tantamount to
gifting extra, albeit conditional income, preserves consumer choice, maximizes
aggregate utility gain among the indigent and minimizes the efficiency and
investment distortions so characteristic of subsidies. Thus designed, the freebidy
proposal is efficient, closed, sustainable, and self-perpetuating.
Despite the break from traditional economic wisdom, and the overtly
unsustainable incentives that it induces, the freebie economy has its
advantages. First, it provides essentials for the really poor. Since a PDS is
in place, it’d be straightforward to replace subsidized goods with rationed
freebies. The strategy, though, is more advantageous with income-elastic luxury
goods than essentials, since it permits ‘judicious’ price discrimination in the
cover of cross-subsidizing of the poor by the rich, and simultaneously serves
to pull the poor up through the lifestyle ladder. For good measure, the freebie
economy is advantageous to ‘Bharat’ as well, for the increase in consumption
among the masses would help expand margins due cost economies of scale. The
‘freebie policy’ is a rational one to adopt when technological advances turn
scarcity to abundance (such as resource discoveries) without a concomitant
increase in demand, or when technological advances increase the rate of
obsolescence in the market. The strategy serves implicitly as a labor supply
control instrument too. If blue collar wages rise unsustainably, as they do
during economic booms, the freebie cut-off percentile falls, forcing those
marginal households to compensate for the loss in freebies by supplying labor,
thus forcing blue collar wages back down. Such strategy is particularly
opportune when unemployment rises, or when wage pressures threaten to stymie
economic growth. And, despite the strategic plays around solid waste, the
freebie strategy serves as a conservation policy too. By offering a limited
amount free, the strategy induces households to constrain their consumption to
the rationed freebie. Such strategy is applicable to environmentally injurious,
albeit essential consumables. In an economic downturn, the strategy keeps the
industrial engine going by offering ‘luxury’ durables to households just below
the percentile cut-off. The opportunity cost of freebidizing such households is
mitigated, on one hand, by interest rates that are at the bottom of the
economic rate cycle, and on the other by lower inventory costs (and by the fall
in the price of durables with the fall in consumer demand during recessions). Implementing
the ‘closed’ freebidy scheme smoothens out the demand for durables and in turn
the inventory of consumer durables. The built-in incentives and dis-incentives in
this proposal drive the economy to find a sweet spot that is a pareto
compromise between, on one hand, equity and efficiency, and on the other
between efficiency and the environment. It even obtains an implicit and endogenous
rate of societal technological advance, as well as product-specific innovation
and obsolescence rates. Over time, the society moves incrementally
toward an environmentally, financially and even a technologically sustainable
welfare state.
Now, for that word in the dictionary…
Dial M for Miracle, Right?