TAKE OR PAYAYA! – A
‘SWOOF’ ON ELECTION CAMPAIGN FINANCING
Ganga Prasad G. Rao
Election campaign financing and reform has been at the
forefront of politics for the undue influence it has on everything from
candidate choice, the platform, the choice of constituencies, the party manifesto
itself, even post-election strategies and policies of parties, whether winners
or otherwise. The lack of a credible, public, legal, and ethical system to
raise finances for election campaigns (and for other normal political
activities) has induced many an ill in our society – from corruption and fraud
to conspiracies, murders and allegation of electoral manipulation with
‘foreign’ money.
One of the primary inadequacies with the existing system which
raises funds from special interests is the overt expectation, post-elections,
of returns, even immediate and substantial, for political contributions made
prior to elections. Such expectations, admittedly difficult to deny post the
electoral win, have resulted in many an administrative lapse/oversight,
mis-guided policies, regulatory loopholes and legal grey zones. The harm to the
economy, in terms of efficiency losses, and the exacerbation of social inequity
could lead to unforeseen, yet large and irreversible consequences in years and
terms in to the future. This realization has spawned many an effort to correct
the problem, most of them revolving around raising Election campaign funds,
ECFs, publicly. Solutions – ranging from involuntary wage deductions, voluntary
contributions with tax returns, or a (sales) tax-surcharge – have been mooted,
but did not find favour for reasons of impracticability, or worse, a ‘who will
bell the cat’ syndrome. Elsewhere, there is the matter of the Government timing
its policies to produce results toward the end of its term, so it could
leverage its incumbency advantage to pull away in the race for financial
contributions and, indeed, with the elections itself. For these and other
reasons, it is necessary to consider alternate means of financing elections and
‘satisficing’ coalition partners and the opposition during the term of the
ruling party.
Let us therefore take a tentative step forward and consider
an admittedly unconventional strategy for financing elections, a strategy that
fills the Election pot with ‘contributions’, Hallelujah!, from friendly and
unfriendly nations across and beyond our borders. But why? And how? The ‘why’,
as it turns out, is easier than the ‘how’. Elections decide the future
direction of the nation for the immediate term, and even for terms to follow.
And wouldn’t friendly and unfriendly nations - trading partners and competitors
– seek to influence that direction much as our MEA seeks to extend its
‘panchsheel-moderated’ influence to SAARC, ASEAN and nations beyond? And if the
future of one nation were inextricably intertwined with the futures of friendly
and competing nations, wouldn’t it make sense to design a system that permitted
each nation to pursue its foreign policies through an overt, legal monetary
route – even one that influenced policy though electoral choices - than through
underground channels that brought diplomatic disrepute?
As for the ‘how’, if there is mutual awareness, if not tacit
recognition of each other’s ‘extra jurisdictional’ monetary influences, then
the same could instead be routed through the Sovereign Wealth Fund, SWF, route.
Every nation has a Sovereign fund, a fund ostensibly meant to protect the
nation’s wealth in the present and the (long) future. Thankfully, these
Sovereign funds operate within and without the confines of one’s own nation, and
against one another, bilaterally and multi-laterally. What if we exploited their
geographical spread across nations to create as many election pots as SWFs, and
framed rules under a ‘Hedge (Opposite) ZS’ paradigm to fill them? A Sovereign
fund, due its decades-, even century-long vision, seeks more than merely a
monetary return; it seeks investments that turn its nation financially,
economically, socially, and environmentally sustainable over that duration. That
‘sustainable threshold return’, determined by wealth, resource endowments, and
technology, will likely approximate the ‘very long-run’ real interest rate (one
can’t do any better with a ‘VLCC’ fund seeking to avoid turbulence in that many
dimensions) over the ‘floor’, the floor being the ‘natural rate of gold price inflation’
(one can always postpone a future for a lowly return that approximately matches
gold inflation). Aware of this band of low returns, the upper boundary of which
varies across nations, the SWFs consciously exploits short- and
intermediate-run ‘market exuberance’ to sweep away gains which have their origins
in excess volatility, excess returns, or a ‘bakey’ on Potential GDP (the
Potential GDP ‘Gap’). These gains find their way in to various pots – overt Foreign
aid and a Strategy fund for extra-jurisdictional legislative initiatives if a
friendly nation, and a 2-pronged ‘Slush funds for covert military assistance
plus a Peace dividend to incentivize economic and military cooperation’, if an
unfriendly nation. Since politics determines who takes over the reins of the
government, the SWF finds it appropriate that the Peace dividend be offered
toward election campaign funds, so the winner, regardless of which party, would
be receptive to a peaceful, co-operative future upon forming the new government.
Nations might differ in the ‘threshold returns’ they set for
their SWF given their resource endowments, stage of development and
expectations for the future. In turn, this translates to varying degrees of
involvement in the capital markets of other nations and implies different
behaviour in the markets, and indeed contributions to the ‘Peace Dividend ECF’.
A rich nation that seeks to be just and sustainable might adopt a lower
threshold return than a developing nation and distribute more of its gains
among ECFs than the latter. Consequently, the rich nation may offer a larger
contribution to the ECF than would a developing nation.
If level changes in the Equity section of the market are
indicative of achieving performance benchmarks or falling short of them, Equity
and Bond volatility of lessons or interim compensation/exploitation, changes in
Bond levels of ‘secular’ reductions/increases in inequity, and Complements of
the presence of ‘opposites and hedges’, then, given nations could be friendly
or competitors, and the ‘home’ government either to the Right, Center, or Left,
there are, potentially, several alternative configurations for the allocation of
SWF funds in Boom and Bust years across asset classes. However, using the
‘principles’ as enunciated above, two illustrative, albeit aggregate allocations
for a pair of SWFs is proposed below:
FRIENDLY NATIONS
NATION
B CAPITAL MARKET
|
Source of Return
|
NATION
A CAPITAL MARKET
|
||
Bond
|
Equity
|
|
Equity
|
Bond
|
|
SovA Comp (20%)
|
Volatility
|
SovB Comp (10%)
|
|
SovA Comp (20%)
|
SovB Key (65%)
|
Level
|
SovA Key (50%)
|
SovB Comp (20%)
|
NationA
Peace Dividend: SovB Bakey(5%)
NationB Peace Dividend: SovA Bakey
(10%)
UNFRIENDLY NATIONS
NATION
B CAPITAL MARKET
|
Source of Return
|
NATION
A CAPITAL MARKET
|
||
Bond
|
Equity
|
|
Equity
|
Bond
|
SovA Comp (10%)
|
SovA Comp (5%)
|
Volatility
|
SovB Comp (10%)
|
SovB Comp (10%)
|
|
SovB Key (50%)
|
Level
|
SovA Key (60%)
|
|
NationA
Peace Dividend: SovB Bakey (30%)
NationB Peace Dividend: SovA Bakey (25%)
Thus structured, the Peace Dividend pot is the sum of gains
from capital markets and strategic residual nations pay each other to avoid
overt military, economic, or diplomatic confrontation in the current time
frame. The pot could also be alternatively interpreted as representing the
monetary translation of resolved and unresolved issues in international trade,
diplomatic/military relationships and social/religious contracts/benchmarks, or
as representing certain viewpoints and (unilateral) decisions by the SWFs. By
the nature of the allocations, the ECFs shrinks when SWFs prefer to stay
invested in peace time, and enlarges in those years when the two nations turn
unfriendly and lock horns with each other. By offering the Peace Dividend
toward the Election Campaign fund, the nations mean as much to share the
‘spoils’ with political parties, as it means to hold them responsible for
correcting the unresolved issues in the new Parliament.
In a multi-lateral context, each nation would be investing across
the capital markets of friendly and unfriendly nations, and the SWF allocations
turn as much more complex. It is suffice to point out, however, that in such
cases, the SWF would invest much less at home and distribute a larger share of
its portfolio in investments abroad. Further, the allocation to any single market
would be a small fraction of its market capitalization and, indeed, of the SWF
net assets. Consequently, the ECF, now comprised of contributions from several
SWFs, would take on an international flavour and seem like an International
Election Fund. Extrapolated to all democratic nations, the ECFs would
constitute a global system for cross-financing of elections.
The focus now shifts to how the monies available under the
Election Fund are apportioned across the various parties – ruling and
opposition. To aid in answering the question, consider a proposal that rewards
and punishes the Ruling party and the Opposition in some relation to their economic
and social performance. In a democracy, parties make ‘offers’ to voters via
their manifesto/agenda and nominate candidates to pursue them. Due the majority
criterion, populist policies – policies that are privately enriching to the
masses in the immediate- or short-run, but zero-sums across time, space, and the
environmental commons, are preferred by voters. Due competition, parties seek
to better one another with their offers, and thus push the more greedy or
desperate amongst themselves to stake a manifesto that implies extreme,
unsustainable exploitation of the commons and future generations. Such economic
exploitation is facilitated by interventions in various economic spheres,
specifically, interest rates, subsidy-induced government borrowing and budget
deficits, exchange rate and trade policy, and industrial policy. A Government
that follows a zero-sum strategy, ‘depreciate ‘n export’, or ‘exploit the
environment’ strategy is likely to:
a) lower
short-term interest rates,
b) lower Corporate/Capital gains/Personal Income taxes,
c) announce populist subsidies that enlarge the budget
deficit and induce an unsustainable fiscal deficit,
d) resort to laxity in enforcing environmental laws and
regulations, and
e) artificially depreciate
currency to boosts exports if at the cost of stoking domestic inflation.
Such interventions lead further to structural imbalances in
bond and savings markets, currency markets, international trade and
environmental protection. An ECF that distributes the Peace Dividend monies
indiscriminately among political parties could exacerbate these tendencies, and
cause irreparable damage to the economic and financial fundamentals of the
nation. To staunch such irreparable economic damage, the ECF must so structure
its ‘payouts’ that it incentivizes prudent and sustainable economic policy decisions
by the political parties.
Toward constructing a ‘rule of thumb’ for ECF payouts across
parties, first conceptualize a Payout Fraction, PF, designed simply as a
counter-weight to the perverse incentives faced by political parties, in
particular, the Ruling party, even if it implies, in the context of politics spanning
the entire 180 degree Left-Right spectrum and the presence of
friendly/unfriendly nations, a certain subjective judgement as to what is
‘appropriate policy’ and what isn’t. Let PF be a product of two variables: a
time-dependent ‘Equity Rating’, Z, and a composite of policy variables and economic
parameters, EPP, that measures the ‘ZS-Exploit’ strategy:
PF = k. Z.EPP
Z, the first component of the PF, constructed as A(t/60) and
A(1- t/60) - where 't' represents the month count from the start of the new
government for a 5 year term - provides for formal cognizance of the public
perception of the government - the so called Approval Rating, A - in the
distribution of electoral funds between the ruling party and the opposition
parties. If the survey for the Approval rate were so designed as to limit itself
to household and social welfare (an indicator of cost of living, livelihood
standards, and social equity), then the above formula would be a time-weighted,
see-saw combination of equity and efficiency measures. It’d apply directly to
the Ruling party, but in the complement to the Opposition. In both cases, the
fraction would vary over time albeit in opposing trends. The ruling party
stands to gain much of initial fund flows from the ECF; conversely, the hand of
the Opposition is strengthened toward the end of the term, thus offering a
credible counter-weight to the incumbency advantage of the existing government.
The second component, EPP, must be designed to offer an
appropriate corrective signal that, when applied to distribute monies from the
ECF, would offer the appropriate disincentives to political parties and force
them to refrain from engaging in short-term exploitive behaviour. That signal
would only obtain if EPP targeted those instruments and policy variables that the
Ruling party employed to exploit, intervene in, or influence outcomes. It is to
the choice (and design) of these instruments, outcomes and policy variables
that we now turn our attention to.
Many governments have exploited the trade-off between economic
growth and the environment to jumpstart their economy. To counter this
incentive, albeit ‘judiciously’, we include as the first term of the PF
equation, the percent GDP growth net of the Inflation in the price of Carbon
Permits; the inflation in the price of carbon permits being an indicator of the
marginal severity of environmental exploitation. If the Government were
environmentally judicious with its growth policies, the net would be positive, implying
its environmental compromises resulted in higher economic growth. Conversely,
poorly conceived, environmentally profligate industrial policies that raise
marginal environmental damage and turn the net negative, take away from the
Payout fraction to the Ruling party. Anticipating that the ECF will deny them
campaign funds for being environmentally insensitive, the Ruling party either
changes course or delays the environmentally injurious decision, thus averting
the environmental wrong.
To the second term in the PF formula, we assign the task of
catching the Government short if it pursues the all-too-familiar Keynesian ‘spend-big-on-subsidies-and-kickstart-the-economy-with-low-interest-rates’
strategy. Such strategy discounts the impact on government finances, in
particular the budget deficit, and in turn leads to both inflation and higher
long bond yields due inter-temporal and cross-sectional ‘crowding out effect’. To
counter such ‘governance short-cuts’, the Payout Fraction is designed inversely
related to the sum of the long-short rate spread and the inflation rate. This
variable increases in magnitude with the extent of intervention and damage, and
helps check any ‘irrational exuberance’ on the part of the Ruling party upon
assumption of office.
The third strategy, that of ‘Depreciate ‘n Export’, involves
intervening in the currency-exchange rate market to artificially depreciate the
currency as a means to turn exports attractive. Such depreciation could be
induced by a variety of tactics: from flooding the economy with excess supply
of currency (M2), sustained selling of domestic currency to buy dollars in the
currency market, to reducing the CRR. The ensuing boost to exports (which supposedly
contributes to GDP growth) is tempered by the hike in inflation and the compensating
rise in bond yields. Thankfully, the Payout Fraction has anticipated the
flagrant exploitation of such a strategy in the bond-inflation summation construct,
and the same is sufficient to internalize this perversity too.
Much like the Budget deficit is exacerbated by populist
subsidies, the Current account deficit too is a reflection of exchange rate and
terms of trade and, thus, is affected by trade policies. The Current account
deficit is determined by the efficacy and the sustainability of exchange rate
interventions. A Government that maliciously adopts a deficit-raising growth
strategy must be held accountable to its voters. The ECF-PF route is a
tentative means to obtain such control. A ratio of GDP growth to the sum of Budget
deficit and Current account deficit reveals the effectiveness of both the
subsidy economy and trade policy; it is a direct variable in the Payout
formula. This ratio assumes values greater than 1 when the percent rise in the
sum of deficits is outdistanced by the percent rise in GDP, and less than 1
vice versa.
Finally, the tendency to either reduce Corporate/Capital
gains tax rate or personal income tax rates to assuage the business community
or middle class voters can be anticipated with a construct that is simply the
ratio of the sum of marginal Corporate, Capital and Persona Income tax rates to
the yield on Long bonds. The rationale is that a reduction in tax revenues must
be compensated for with the issue of more long bonds (short bonds would come to
roost within one’s own term); in turn, raising long bonds incrementally causes its
yield to increase. This construct trends in opposite direction to the short-run
incentives of the Ruling party and serves to brake those unsustainable
ambitions.
Combining the above ‘arguments’ of the EPP function, the
Payout Fraction takes the form:
PF = k. Z. EPP{ [ (ybl-ybs)+ip]
, [GDP^/(db+dca)^], [GDP^- Pcp^] , [(tc+tcg+tpi)/ybl]
}
where
^: percent growth rate of the relevant variable
Z = A(t/60) - Opposition; A(1-t/60) - Ruling party
ip: (Price) Inflation
ybl: Long Bond Yield
ybs: Short Bond Yield
db: Budget Deficit
dca: Current Account Deficit
tc: Corporate Tax
tcg: Capital Gains Tax
tpi: Personal Income Tax
Pcp: Price of Carbon Permit
Together, these variables measure the net impact of biased,
politically motivated, or economically indefensible interventions in domestic,
trade, taxation, currency, and goods markets. The Payout Fraction, tentatively proposed
above, when computed and combined with the aggregate ECF pot for the nation (as
determined by contributions from various SWFs operating in the nation’s capital
markets) determines the flow of election funds to the Ruling and opposition parties.
Thus designed, the Payout Fraction offers the right incentives to political
parties no matter on which side of the government they sit on. It achieves the
goal of ‘equitably’ distributing the ‘Bakey-Largesse-Sting’ from the SWFs among
political parties who determine the economic course of the nation.
The upfront knowledge of the Payout Function, and the fact
that any lapse in policy making enriches the opponent, ensures political
parties anticipate their gains and losses under alternative strategies, re-consider
incentives before and after the elections, and internalize the same in their
policy promulgations. Finally, the advantage that the Ruling party has in terms
of determining the size of its own Payoff (and that too, immediately) due
promulgating policy at the start of the term is counter-balanced by the design
of the Payoff function which enriches the Opposition toward the end of the term
when SWFs are likely particularly active and when public opinion turns
absolutely critical to survival.
The proposal above is, in the context of the globalized
society we live in and the realities of the day, a practical solution to the
issue of Electoral and Party financing. It obtains a degree of control on the
perverse incentives facing political parties in elections by offering them a
publicly credible and legal source of funds for campaigning, and guides the
nation toward an equitable and an efficient economy by inducing prudent and
enlightened policy making.
Besides, it leaves something citizens relish on their dinner
plates…
…. A Corruption Bakey!